3.3.4. Relationships
3.3.4.1. Introduction
Economic growth can either be achieved by increasing the factor inputs to production,
such as capital and labor, or by increasing productivity (i.e., the efficiency
by which factors of production are used to generate economic output). Without
productivity growth, long-run output growth cannot be maintained with limited
or depletable resource inputs; as a result, complex societies become increasingly
vulnerable (Tainter, 1988). Changes between inputs and outputs are usually analyzed
by drawing upon the production function approach pioneered by Tinbergen (1942)
and Solow (1957). Yet, empirical analyses (e.g., Denison, 1962, 1985) quickly
identified that quality and composition of factor inputs are more important
in explaining long-run output growth than merely the quantitative growth in
available factor inputs. For instance, at first sight population growth might
be considered as central for economic growth, because it increases the labor
force. Upon closer examination, however, institutional and social factors that
govern working-time regulation, female workforce participation, and above all
the qualification of the workforce (education) have been more important determinants
of long-run economic growth (Denison, 1962, 1985) than simple growth in the
numbers of the potential workforce (usually calculated as the population in
the age bracket 15 to 65 years). Another puzzling finding of Solow (1957) is
that, even when changes in quality and composition of factors of production
are accounted for, increases in per capita economic output (productivity) remain
largely unexplained, a "residual" in the analysis remains unclear (for a review,
see Griliches, 1996). The "residual," is usually ascribed to "advances in knowledge
and technology" which, unlike capital and labor, cannot be measured directly.
However, it might also be the result of other influences, which potentially
include growing contributions to the economy by non-market or under-priced natural
resources. Thus, considerable measurement and interpretative uncertainties remain
in the explanation of productivity growth.
New approaches and models extended the neoclassic growth model (e.g., Romer,
1986; Lucas, 1988; Grossmann and Helpman, 1991, 1993). In these, increases in
human capital through education and the importance of technological innovation
via directed activity (research and development (R&D)) complement more traditional
approaches, which represents a return to the earlier work of Schumpeter (1943),
Kuznets (1958), Nelson et al. (1967), and Landes (1969).
3.3.4.2. Influence of Demographics
Neoclassic economic growth theory embraces as a general principle the notion
that long-term per capita income growth rate is independent of population growth
rate. Thus, a rapidly growing population should not necessarily slow down a
countries' economic development. Blanchet (1991) summarizes the country-level
data. Prior to 1980, the overwhelming majority of studies showed no significant
correlation between population growth and economic growth (National Research
Council, 1986). Recent correlation studies, however, suggest a statistically
significant, but weak, inverse relationship for the 1970s and 1980s, despite
no correlation being established previously (Blanchet, 1991). As noted in Section
3.2, the reverse effect of income growth on demographics is much clearer.
Population aging is another consideration advanced as having significant influence
on economic growth rates. Reductions in workforce availability and excessive
social security and pension expenditures are cited as possible drivers. Section
3.2 above concluded that evidence for a strong negative impact is rather
elusive. Two additional points deserve consideration. First, population aging
is not necessarily the best indicator for workforce availability, because while
the percentage of the elderly, in particular those of retirement age, increases,
the proportion of younger people (of pre-work or -career age) decreases. As
a result, the percentage of the working age population (age 15 to 65 years)
in the total population changes less dramatically, even in scenarios of pronounced
aging. For instance, in the IIASA low population scenario (7 billion world population
by 2100) discussed in Section 3.2, the percentage
of age categories 15 to 65 years changes from 62% in 1995 to 54% by 2100. This
percentage falls to 48% in the regions with the highest population aging (Lutz
et al., 1996).
A second point is that these demographic variables only indicate potential
workforce numbers. Actual gainfully employed workforce numbers are influenced
by additional important variables - unemployment levels, female workforce participation
rates, and finally working time. The importance of these variables can be illustrated
by a few statistics. Currently, about 40 million people are unemployed in the
OECD countries (UNDP, 1997). The female workforce participation ratios vary
enormously, from about 10% to 48% of the workforce (as in Saudi Arabia and Sweden,
respectively; UNDP, 1997), and have been changing dramatically over time. For
the US, for instance, female workforce participation rates increased from 17%
in 1890 (US DOC, 1975) to 45% in 1990 (UNDP, 1997). Similar dramatic long-term
changes have occurred in the number of working hours in all industrial countries.
Compared to the mid-19th century, the number of average working hours has declined
from about 3000 to about 1500 (Maddison, 1995; Ausubel and Grübler, 1995). However,
in most OECD countries the trend in working time reductions has slowed to a
halt since the early 1980s (Marchand, 1992).
Thus, unless the rather implausible assumption is made that with population
aging all these other important determinants of labor input remain unchanged,
the impacts of aging are likely to be compensated by corresponding changes in
these variables (e.g. greater female workforce participation, earlier retirement,
etc.). Finally, it must be reiterated that qualitative labor force characteristics,
most notably education, are a more important determinant for long-run productivity
and hence economic growth than mere workforce numbers.
3.3.4.3. Influence of Social and Institutional Changes
The importance of social and institutional changes to provide conditions that
enabled the acceleration of the Industrial Revolution is widely acknowledged
(Rosenberg and Birdzell, 1986, 1990). Rostow (1990) and Landes (1969) identify
many social and cultural factors in the "preconditions for economic acceleration"
and in the process of economic development.
The importance of institutions and stable social environments is also increasingly
discussed in the literature concerned with current economic growth (World Bank,
1991, 1998a). Barro (1997), and Barro and Sala-I-Martin (1995) report a statistically
significant relationship between rule-of-law and democracy indices with per
capita GDP growth. Law enforcement and legal rights are important indicators
for human development in their own right, but enforceable legal contracts are
equally important for markets to function. Other socio-institutional factors
have been identified that are important to productivity and economic growth:
education is mentioned above. Income inequality (and resultant social tensions)
also appears to correlate negatively with economic development (World Bank,
1998a; Maddison, 1995).
Strong parallels run between social, institutional, and technological changes
(Grübler, 1998a; OECD, 1998a). In particular, many features common to the processes
of evolution in biologic organisms have been found (e.g., Teilhard de Chardin,
1959; Hayek, 1967; Matthews, 1984; Dawkins, 1986; Michaelis, 1997c). Thus, to
understand these processes would involve:
- A search for new behaviors, institutions, and social or cultural patterns.
- Experimentation with those that are found.
- Various methods of selecting the "fit" or "desirable" changes.
- Various methods of perpetuating and diffusing those changes that are selected.
Many aspects of the processes of technical change (e.g., its unpredictability
and the importance of mechanisms such as path-dependence and "lock-in") also
apply to social change.
It is obviously difficult to evaluate the role of social, cultural, and institutional
changes in economic and technical development. Whereas the monetary and technological
aspects of change are often measurable and can be observed on a relatively "objective"
basis, social, cultural, and institutional processes are hard to measure and
often subjective. They tend to involve personal interactions among people, sometimes
large numbers of people, over long periods.
Nonetheless, these factors must be taken into account in the scenarios. The
SRES approach to develop qualitative scenario "storylines" that provide an overall
framework and background for quantitative scenario assumptions and model runs
can be considered a particularly valuable strength. Storylines allow these issues
to be addressed explicitly, even if current knowledge does not allow social,
cultural, and institutional factors to be treated in a rigid, quantitative (not
to mention deterministic) way.
|