Working Group III: Mitigation |
|
|
Other reports in this collection |
9.2.9 Services Since services employ more people and since they are much more employment-intensive than energy and manufacturing, employment usually increases as a result of GHG mitigation. However, the effects are small and diffused, and there is hardly any literature on specific sectoral effects for the service industries apart from the multisectoral studies reviewed in section 9.2.1 above. 9.2.10 HouseholdsThe impact of mitigation on households comes directly through changes in the
technology and price of household use of energy for heat, light, and power,
and indirectly through macroeconomic effects, particularly on the income of
households and the employment of their members. An important ancillary benefit
for households is the potential improvement in quality of indoor, local, and
regional air. Most studies analyze the effect of mitigation strategies on GDP, which is often taken as an indicator of welfare. However, this measure does not capture the effects on the distribution of income between households. There are some studies that look at private consumption and other constructed indices of welfare, but these are few in number. This literature concentrates more on the developed economies, as these are the countries that would be taking actions first to reduce the emissions. The effect on developing economies is indirect through the trade effects and energy price effect. 9.2.10.1 Distributional Effects of MitigationThese are mainly discussed in Chapter 8 (Section 8.2.2.3). There are a number of studies on the domestic income distributional effects of carbon taxation, mostly for developed countries (Johnson et al., 1990; Chandler and Nicholls, 1990; Poterba, 1991; Bertram et al., 1993; Hamilton and Cameron, 1994; Symons et al., 1994; Cornwall and Creedy, 1996). These studies show a regressive effect of carbon taxes, but a progressive effect if revenues are returned to disadvantaged groups. As the share of household expenditure on energy and the dependence on high-carbon fuels of the lower income groups is high, the impact of a carbon tax would be disproportionately higher on these lower income groups (Goldemberg and Johansson, 1995; Yamasaki and Tominaga, 1997). Barker and Kòhler (1998) review a number of studies on impact of carbon taxation on households. Their analysis of an EU carbon tax indicates that taxation on domestic energy is regressive and taxation on road fuels is weakly progressive. They also show that revenues recycled through employer taxes could increase disposable income for all income groups in the study. 9.2.10.2 Electricity and Demand-side ManagementA number of studies point out that power sector deregulation and competition
will improve the efficiency of operations as well as management, which will
result in a reduction in electricity rate charged to the end users (Hsu and
Tchen, 1997). Demand-side management (DSM) instituted by electric utilities
would increase electricity prices, but could lead to a reduction in total bills
to participating customers (Hirst and Hadley, 1995), although the increased
electricity prices could deter companies from using these measures in a competitive
market. Parker (1995) indicated that DSM measures could lead to job creation
from production and installation of equipment. 9.2.10.3 Effects of Improvement in Energy Efficiency
|
Other reports in this collection |