4.6 Market and Non-market Options to Enhance, Maintain, and
Manage Carbon Pools
4.6.1. Introduction, Taxes, and Quotas
There are a host of market and non-market options to manage carbon pools in
the terrestrial biosphere. Some of the most relevant questions related to carbon
sequestration deal with the types of instruments, policies, and mechanisms that
could play a role in promoting increased sequestration and how the various arrangements
would actually affect outcomes. Market mechanisms could be important in promoting
or discouraging carbon sequestration. Potential mechanisms might include taxes
or subsidies for activities that affect carbon directly or that affect activities
with large carbon implications. The UK, for example, has proposed a Climate
Change Levy to be adopted by the UKs 2001 Budget. The Kyoto Protocol
introduces flexible mechanisms allowing joint implementation, emissions trading,
and the clean development mechanism. When dealing with terrestrial systems any
policies that influence land use can affect carbon sequestration. Finally, there
is the question of how the various instruments and policies are likely to influence
leakage of carbon flows outside the targetted system.
Agricultural subsidies are common in many, if not most, countries. Agricultural
subsidies and absent forestry subsidy policies can often be viewed as discouraging
forest production and thus, inadvertently, discouraging some possibilities for
carbon sequestration. Similarly, tax policies can promote or discourage certain
types of land use. In some countries, however, subsidies do promote afforestation
and reforestation. The movement of land from agriculture to forests generally
leads to gains in the forest sector and losses in the agricultural sector. The
cost of any additional carbon storage can involve a change in welfare across
two sectors. Lower taxes for agricultural lands and subsidies for forest clearing
may be part of the package of instruments to promote development.
To reach objectives for carbon sequestration, market mechanisms are important,
but an appropriate institutional setting is also useful. In some tropical countries
the profitability of maintaining forests could be improved in order to prevent
conversion to alternative uses of the land. Success could entail revising policies
that directly or indirectly subsidize cattle ranching (as has been historically
the case in Latin America) or agriculture. Success in C sequestration could
also entail technical and financial training and capacity building at the local
level. It should be recognized, however, that in many tropical countries, particularly
within Asia and Africa, forests are harvested and used according to the subsistence
needs of local communities. In these cases, some have argued that approaches
based on market mechanisms will not be effective. Also, non-timber forest products
are an important component of the total demand for forest products and could
be considered.
It is clear that some measures aimed at sequestering C in the biosphere have
relatively low cost compared to other approaches for mitigating the atmospheric
increase of CO2 (Section 4.5). However, to
date only a small number of projects involving a small and varied group of stakeholders
has been initiated in the terrestrial biosphere. These projects (forest expansion,
forest management, soil carbon management, community forestry, and agroforestry)
have covered, worldwide, an area of 3.6 to 6.4 million hectares in 1999 (for
an overview see Brown et al., 2000). Incentives that would create projects aimed
at carbon sequestration in the biosphere on a large scale are not yet in place.
An important change in motivating carbon sequestration has been the creation
of the Kyoto Protocol, in December 1997. Although few countries have yet to
ratify the Kyoto Protocol, it introduces ceilings and/or quotas for CO2
emissions for Annex B countries. In addition, the Kyoto Protocol explicitly
recognizes afforestation, reforestation, and deforestation (ARD) as having carbon
implications, and it provides credits (and debits) for these activities in meeting
carbon-emissions targets. This arrangement has contributed to pressures to find
ways to give sequestered carbon value in the market place. A detailed explanation
of how the Kyoto Protocol might influence management of C stocks is given in
the IPCC Special Report on LULUCF (IPCC, 2000a).
Through setting emissions targets and introducing taxes on CO2 emission
in some countries, carbon gains monetary value and could become a new product
for the forestry sector. From existing emissions taxes this value is estimated
at US$200/tCO2 in Norway and US$100/tCO2 in the Netherlands
(Solberg, 1997; Nabuurs, 1998). In the case of the Netherlands, this carbon
value is equivalent to US$17.5/m3 of roundwood, more than the stumpage value
of wood as a raw material. However, in the first trades of certified carbon
credits, Moura-Costa and Stuart (1998) found that prices ranged between US$5US$10/tC.
More generally, Moura-Costa and Stuart (1998) found that the average price for
carbon credits for carbon sequestered in developing countries ranged from US$0.19
to US$12/tC, and that these differences are very much linked to uncertainty
about long term policy.
The Dutch Government is considering the introduction of CO2 certificates
as part of a test of CO2 emissions trading. In this system, each
economic sector and each firm could achieve its targets partly through certificates.
Funds generated from these certificates would be used to establish forests.
|