6.4.3 International Co-ordination of Policy Packages
When developing domestic policies to meet their emissions limitation commitments
under the Kyoto Protocol, some Annex I Parties may wish, or be under pressure,
to impose less stringent obligations on some industries to improve their competitiveness.
The sensitivity of industry location to the stringency of environmental regulation
is called ecological dumping. International co-ordination of environmental
policies may be needed to reach an economically efficient outcome in which it
is impossible to make one country better off without making at least one other
country worse off.
Under certain ideal conditions (e.g., perfect competition in all markets) there
is theoretically no need for international policy co-ordination (Oates and Schwab,
1988). However, such conditions do not hold if there is imperfect competition
in goods markets or unemployment (Rauscher, 1991, 1994; Barrett, 1994; Kennedy,
1994; A. Ulph, 1994; D. Ulph, 1994). If, and to what extent, international differences
in environmental regulation have trade or even relocation implications obviously
depends on a host of factors. These include country size, availability of alternatives,
relative resource endowment, mobility of production factors, competition level,
scope for innovation, possibility of border-tax adjustment, chances of retaliation,
and redistribution of environmental tax revenues (OECD, 1996a).
Although it is clear that many factors affect the relationship between the
stringency of pollution control policies (if implemented unilaterally) and net
exports, some authors have carried out rather straightforward empirical tests
on the relationship between the two variables. Han and Braden (1996) examined
19 US manufacturing industries between 1973 and 1990 with the help of regression
analysis. They found the relationship between pollution abatement costs and
net exports to be negative in most of the sample period, but diminishing over
time (with elasticities close to zero in many industries). Van Beers and Van
den Bergh (1997), using a gravity model of international trade and two measures
of environmental stringency, did not find a significant relationship between
environmental stringency and total exports for the dirty industries.
However, when they focused on the non-resource based, and therefore more mobile,
industries only this relationship was significant.
Early empirical research on the impact of environmental policy on trade found
little evidence of a measurable relationship, partly because of low environmental
taxes and partly through data and statistical limitations. Therefore, many studies
have concentrated on simulations of environmental tax regimes. From a survey
of these studies, IPCCs SAR (IPCC, 1996) concluded that estimates of the
effects of environmental policies (notably carbon taxes) on trade vary wildly,
depending on model parameters (such as energy demand elasticities and assumptions
regarding the substitutability of traded goods) and the policy scenario examined
(extent of reduction in emissions and extent of international co-ordination).
Various partial equilibrium models have been designed to analyze ecological
dumping, many using static or dynamic game theory. Early analyses used a Cournot
setting, which models long-run competition among firms as a series of strategic
capacity or output choices. The general conclusion from these early models is
that the optimal tax (or any comparable domestic environmental policy instrument)
would be set below marginal damage. As a consequence, environmental policies
are designed to try to protect domestic industries. If producers collude, however,
the incentive for governments to engage in ecological dumping is reduced (Ulph,
1993).
The ecological dumping conclusion could change completely if governments act
strategically in setting taxes, and if there is Bertrand competition (firms
compete by choosing the price to charge, rather than the quantity to produce)
instead of Cournot competition (Eaton and Grossman, 1986; Barrett, 1994; Conrad,
1996; Ulph, 1996). If, however, producers act strategically or can collude,
then the outcome in terms of ecological dumping is not straightforward. Quantity-based
environmental regulation, if implemented unilaterally in a duopolistic case
with a domestic and foreign supplier, might actually benefit domestic firms
at the cost of domestic consumers (Kooiman, 1998). If both governments and producers
act strategically, again, the incentive for governments to distort the environmental
policy is less than when only governments acted strategically, so that the Bertrand
outcome can be similar to the Cournot outcome (Ulph, 1996).
Ecological dumping also has been analyzed with the help of general equilibrium
models of international trade involving externalities (Rauscher, 1994). It was
shown that in a second-best world for several market structuresmonopoly
power of the exposed sector or oligopoly on an outside market (Elbers and Withagen,
1999)ecological dumping might not (always) be beneficial from a welfare
point of view. This is contrary to the conclusions of some of the earlier partial
equilibrium models.
The most interesting case for analyzing policy co-ordination needs is that
in which national commitments have been decided internationally, but individual
Parties may, but need not, co-ordinate their national policies to fulfil their
commitments. This would be the Kyoto Protocol case, after ratification. Hoel
(1997) has addressed this case and argues that governments may tend to subsidize
indirectly particular imperfectly competitive industries selling on the international
market. To prevent this from happening, an argument can be made in favour of
policy co-ordination, which is possible but not required in the Kyoto Protocol,
except insofar as the Kyoto mechanisms are concerned.101
|