6.5.3 The Effects of Alternative Policy Instruments on Technological Change
In the long run, the development and widespread adoption of new technologies
can greatly ameliorate what, in the short run, sometimes appear to be overwhelming
conflicts between economic well being and environmental quality. Therefore,
the effect of public policies on the development and spread of new technologies
may be among the most important determinants of success or failure in environmental
protection (Kneese and Schultze, 1975).
To achieve widespread benefits from a new technology, three steps are required
(Schumpeter, 1942):
- invention, the development of a new technical idea;
- innovation, the incorporation of a new idea into a commercial product or
process and the first marketplace implementation thereof; and
- diffusion, the typically gradual process by which improved products or processes
become widely used.
Rates of invention, innovation, and technology diffusion are affected by opportunities
that exist for firms and individuals to profit from investing in research, in
commercial development, and in marketing and product development (Stoneman,
1983).
Governments often seek to influence each of these directly, by investment in
public research, subsidies to research and technological development, dissemination
of information, and other means (Mowery and Rosenberg, 1989). Policies with
large economic impacts, such as those intended to address global climate change,
can be designed to foster technological invention, innovation, and diffusion
(Kemp and Soete, 1990). For the impact of R&D policies on technology development
and transfer, see the IPCC Special Report on Technology Transfer (IPCC, 2000).
To examine the link between policy instruments and technological change, environmental
policies can be characterized as market-based approaches, performance standards,
technology standards, and voluntary agreements. All these forms of intervention
have the potential to induce or force some amount of technological change, because
by their very nature they induce or require firms to do things they would not
otherwise do. Performance and technology standards can be explicitly designed
to be technology forcing, mandating performance levels that are
not currently viewed as technologically feasible or mandating technologies that
are not fully developed. The problem with this approach can be that while regulators
typically assume that some amount of improvement over existing technology will
always be feasible, it is impossible to know how much. Standards must either
be made not very ambitious, or else run the risk of being ultimately unachievable,
which leads to great political and economic disruption (Freeman and Haveman,
1972). However, in the case of obstructed technology, regulators know quite
well the technology improvements that are feasible. Thus, although the problem
of standards being either too low or too ambitious remains a possibility, it
does not make standards inherently incapable of implementing some portion of
the available technology base, and to do so cost-effectively on the basis of
costbenefit tests.106
|