8.2.2 Domestic Policy Instruments and Net Mitigation Costs
Tapping the technical abatement potentials requires setting up new incentive
structures (taxes, emissions trading, technical standards, voluntary agreements,
subsidies) for production and consumption, i.e. climate policies. In the following,
empirical models that measure net mitigation costs of climate policies are reviewed
in order to disentangle the reasons why certain policy packages have similar
or different outcomes in various countries. As a first step, the results are
presented at an aggregated level; then the impact of measures meant to mitigate
the sectoral and distributional consequences of climate policies is examined.
Finally, in a third step, the ancillary benefits from the joint reduction of
carbon emissions and other pollutants are considered to complete the picture.
8.2.2.1 Aggregate Assessment of Revenue-raising Instruments
Introducing a carbon tax (or auctioned tradable permits) provides an incentive
to change the technology over the short and long term. Such policies generate
tax revenues and the way these revenues are used has major impacts on the social
costs of the climate policy. The reason is that these revenues are, in principle,
available to offset some or all of the costs of the mitigation policy. When
emission targets go beyond the negative cost potentials, there is a general
agreement among economists (see Chapters 6 and 7)
that if standards are used (or if emissions permits are allocated for free)
the resultant social cost is higher than the total abatement expenditures. Producers
pass part of the marginal abatement cost on to consumers through higher selling
prices, which implies a loss of consumer surplus. If the elasticity of supply
is quite high, this might lead to a net loss of producer surplus. However, if
the elasticity of supply is fairly low, overall (or net) producer surplus can
rise when policies cause a restriction in output, because the policy-generated
rents per unit of production enjoyed by producers more than compensate for the
net decrease in sales.
In the 1990s there was considerable interest in how revenue-neutral carbon
taxes may mitigate this effect on the economy by enabling the government to
cut the marginal rates of pre-existing taxes, such as income, payroll, and sales
taxes. The possibility is a double dividend policy (Pearce, 1992), by both (1)
improving the environment and (2) offsetting at least part of the welfare losses
of climate policies by reducing the costs of the tax system (see the discussion
in Chapter 7). The same mechanism occurs when nationally
auctioned permits are used; for simplicity, the term carbon tax is used in the
rest of this chapter, except when the distinction between these two instruments
is necessary.
The starting point in a discussion of a double dividend is how expensive it
is to raise government income, that is, how big is the marginal cost of funds
(MCF). A high MCF gives more scope for a double dividend than a small MCF in
the economy. This arises because the parameters that determine the magnitude
of the double-dividend (see Chapter 7) are:
- direct cost to the regulated sector (sectors changes in production
methods or installation of pollution-abatement equipment);
- tax-interaction effect (prices are increasing);
- revenue-recycling effect associated with using revenues to finance cuts
in marginal tax rates.
Figure 8.3: Carbon taxes and the costs of environmental policies.
|
When the revenues of carbon taxes are returned in a lump-sum fashion to households
and firms, the tax-interaction effect is systematically higher than the revenue-recycling
effect. Also the net cost of climate policy is higher than its gross cost (while
lower than that with a no-tax policy, see A1 and A2 in
Figure 8.3). However, it is possible to improve this result
by targetting tax revenues to cuts in the most distortionary taxes; this can
yield either a weak or a strong form of double dividend (Goulder, 1995a). The
weak double dividend occurs as long as there is a revenue-recycling effect due
to the swap between carbon taxes and the most distortionary taxes. Mitigation
costs are systematically lower when revenues are recycled this way than when
they are returned lump sum. The strong double dividend is more difficult to
obtain. It requires that the (beneficial) revenue-recycling effect more than
offset the combination of the primary cost and the tax-interaction effect. In
this case, the net cost of abatement is negative (at least within some range).
As discussed in Chapter 7, this is possible if, prior
to the introduction of the mitigation policy, the tax system is already highly
inefficient along non-environmental dimensions. In terms of Figure
8.3, the revenue-recycling effect is represented by the downward shift from
curve A1 to curve A2 or A3. If the shift is
from A1 to A2, the weak double dividend occurs, but not
the strong double dividend. If the shift is from A1 to A3,
not only does the weak double dividend occur, but the strong double dividend
is realized as well, since the net costs are negative within a range.
While the weak form of double dividend enjoys broad support from theoretical
and numerical studies, the strong double dividend hypothesis is less broadly
supported and more controversial. Indeed, reaching an economical dividend is
impossible when the economy is at full employment and if all other taxation
is optimal (abstracting for the environmental externality). Therefore, it may
be argued that the double dividend accrues from the tax reform, independently
of the climate policy. However, empirical models capture the fact that, in the
real world, a carbon tax or auctioned emissions permits will not be implemented
after the enforcement of an optimal fiscal reform. To the contrary, introducing
a new tax may be a sine qua non condition to the fiscal reform. For a
given carbon tax revenue, models help interpret the best way to recycle this
revenue.
Specific features of the tax systems and markets of the production factors
(labour, capital, and energy) ultimately determine the presence or absence of
a strong double dividend. For example, a double dividend is likely if production
factors are very distorted by prior taxation or specific market conditions,
if there is a problem of trade-balance because of the import of fossil energy,
or if consumer choice is highly distorted because of tax-deducible spending
provisions (Parry and Bento, 2000).
Empirical studies try to gauge the impact of these many determinants and to
understand why the effects of a given recycling strategy (reducing payroll,
personal income, corporate income, investment income, or expenditure taxes)
differ from one country to another.
|