8.2.4.1 The Evaluation of the Ancillary Public Health Impacts
Studies estimating ancillary public health impacts from climate policies were
examined, relying on three surveys of this literature (Ekins, 1996; Burtraw
et al., 1999; Kverndokk and Rosendahl, 2000) and on summaries of the
older literature, supplemented by some of the newer studies. Table
8.5 provides a description of each study, as well as the estimates of ancillary
benefits per tonne of carbon. Table 8.6 summarizes the
modelling choices of the studies reviewed.
Table 8.5: Scenarios and results of studies
on ancillary benefit reviewed |
|
Study |
Area and sectors
|
Scenarios
(1996 US$)
|
Average
ancillary
benefits
US$/tC;
1996 US$)
|
Key pollutants
|
Major endpoints
|
|
Dessus and OConnor, 1999
|
Chile (benefits in Santiago only) |
Tax of US$67 (10% carbon reduction)
Tax of US$157 (20% carbon reduction)
Tax of US$284 (30% carbon reduction)
|
251
254
267 |
Seven air pollutants |
Healthmorbidity and mortality, |
Cifuentes et al., 2000 |
Santiago, Chile |
Energy efficiency
|
62 |
SO2, NOx, CO, NMHC
Indirect estimations for
PM10 and resuspended dust |
Health |
Garbaccio et al., 2000 |
China 29 sectors
(4 energy) |
Tax of US$1/tC
Tax of US$2/tC |
52
52 |
PM10, SO2 |
Health |
Wang and Smith, 1999 |
China power and
household sectors |
Supply-side energy efficiency
improvement
Least-cost per unit global-warmingreduction
fuel substitution
Least-cost per unit human-air-pollutionexposure-
reduction fuel substitution |
|
PM, SO2 |
Health |
Aunan et al. 2000,
Kanudia and Loulou , 1998a |
Hungary |
Energy Conservation Programme |
508 |
TSP, SO2, NOx, CO, VOC,
CO2, CH4, N2O |
Health effects; materials damage;
vegetation damage |
Brendemoen and
Vennemo, 1994 |
Norway |
Tax US$840/tC |
246 |
SO2, NOx, CO, VOC, CO2,
CH4, N2O, Particulates |
Indirect: health costs; lost
recreational value from lakes
forests, ; corrosion
Direct: traffic noise, road
maintenance, congestion,
accidents |
Barker and Rosendahl, 2000 |
Western Europe
(19 regions) |
Tax US$161/tC |
153 |
SO2, NOx, PM10 |
Human and animal health and
welfare, materials, buildings and
other physical capital, vegetation |
Scheraga and Leary, 1993 |
USA |
US$144/tC |
41 |
TSP, PM10, SOx, NOx,
CO, VOC, CO2, Pb |
Health morbidity and mortality |
Boyd et al., 1995 |
USA |
US$9/tC |
40 |
Pb, PM, SOx, SO4, O3 |
Health, visibility |
Abt Associates and
Pechan-Avanti Group, 1999 |
USA |
Tax US$30/tC
Tax US$67/tC |
8
68 |
Criteria pollutants |
Health mortality and illness;
Visibility and household soiling
(materials damage) |
Burtraw et al., 1999 |
USA |
Tax US$10/tC
Tax US$25/tC
Tax US$50/tC |
3
2
2 |
SO2, NOx |
Health |
|
The Burtraw et al. (1999) review of US ancillary benefit studies of public
health impacts linked to mitigation policies applied to the electricity sector
came to several important conclusions:
- Estimates from early studies of ancillary benefits tended to exceed later
ones because of the formers use of more crude and less disaggregate
modelling.
- Studies that did not factor into the baseline the reductions in conventional
pollutants required under the 1990 Clean Air Act estimated benefits an order
of magnitude larger than the studies that did include the 1990 Clean Air Act
in the baseline. Analyzing Ekins (1996), Burtraw et al. (1999) found
that whether the Second Sulphur Protocol is added to the baseline or not can
alter the estimate of ancillary benefit by over 30%.
- Some studies did not consider the bounceback effect (i.e.,
the offsetting increase in conventional pollutants) when a less carbon-intensive
technology is substituted for a more intensive one in response to a carbon
mitigation policy.
- Ancillary benefit estimates are very sensitive to assumptions about the
mortality risk coefficient and the value of statistical life (VSL). Routine
values used in the literature can lead to a difference of 300% in ancillary
benefit estimates.
- Burtraw et al. (1999) and earlier studies to reconcile US and European
estimates for the social costs of fuel cycles found that population density
differences between Europe and the USA account for 2 to 3 times larger benefit
estimates in Europe. Also, the fact that much East Coast US pollution is blown
out to sea while European pollution is blown inland can account for large
ancillary benefit differences.
- With a cap on SO2 emissions, abatement cost savings are considered
ancillary benefits of a carbon policy unless the reductions are so large that
the cap becomes non-binding. When this happens, with SO2 effects
on mortality being as large as they appear to be, ancillary benefits increase
in a discontinuous and rapid fashion, as the health benefits begin to be counted.
Kverndokk and Rosendahl (2000) review much of the recent ancillary benefit
literature in the Nordic countries, UK, and Ireland, concluding that benefits
are of the same order of magnitude as gross (i.e., private) mitigation
costs. They also conclude that the benefits should be viewed as highly uncertain,
because of the use of simplistic tools and transfers of doseresponse and
valuation functions from studies done in other countries. They point out that
most of the Norwegian studies use expert judgement instead of established doseresponse
functions and estimates of national damages per tonne rather than distinguishing
where emissions changes occur and exposures are reduced. Also, they point out
that large differences in ancillary benefits per tonne across several Norwegian
studies can be attributed to differences in energy demand and energy substitution
elasticities. If energy production is reduced rather than switched to less carbon-intensive
fuels, ancillary benefits will be far larger. Kverndokk and Rosendahl (2000)
point out also that studies that feed environmental benefits back into the economic
model add significantly to ancillary benefits.
|