9.2.9 Services
Since services employ more people and since they are much more employment-intensive
than energy and manufacturing, employment usually increases as a result of GHG
mitigation. However, the effects are small and diffused, and there is hardly
any literature on specific sectoral effects for the service industries apart
from the multisectoral studies reviewed in section 9.2.1
above.
9.2.10 Households
The impact of mitigation on households comes directly through changes in the
technology and price of household use of energy for heat, light, and power,
and indirectly through macroeconomic effects, particularly on the income of
households and the employment of their members. An important ancillary benefit
for households is the potential improvement in quality of indoor, local, and
regional air.
Most studies analyze the effect of mitigation strategies on GDP, which is often
taken as an indicator of welfare. However, this measure does not capture the
effects on the distribution of income between households. There are some studies
that look at private consumption and other constructed indices of welfare, but
these are few in number. This literature concentrates more on the developed
economies, as these are the countries that would be taking actions first to
reduce the emissions. The effect on developing economies is indirect through
the trade effects and energy price effect.
9.2.10.1 Distributional Effects of Mitigation
These are mainly discussed in Chapter 8 (Section
8.2.2.3). There are a number of studies on the domestic income distributional
effects of carbon taxation, mostly for developed countries (Johnson et al.,
1990; Chandler and Nicholls, 1990; Poterba, 1991; Bertram et al., 1993;
Hamilton and Cameron, 1994; Symons et al., 1994; Cornwall and Creedy,
1996). These studies show a regressive effect of carbon taxes, but a progressive
effect if revenues are returned to disadvantaged groups. As the share of household
expenditure on energy and the dependence on high-carbon fuels of the lower income
groups is high, the impact of a carbon tax would be disproportionately higher
on these lower income groups (Goldemberg and Johansson, 1995; Yamasaki and Tominaga,
1997). Barker and Kòhler (1998) review a number of studies on impact
of carbon taxation on households. Their analysis of an EU carbon tax indicates
that taxation on domestic energy is regressive and taxation on road fuels is
weakly progressive. They also show that revenues recycled through employer taxes
could increase disposable income for all income groups in the study.
9.2.10.2 Electricity and Demand-side Management
A number of studies point out that power sector deregulation and competition
will improve the efficiency of operations as well as management, which will
result in a reduction in electricity rate charged to the end users (Hsu and
Tchen, 1997). Demand-side management (DSM) instituted by electric utilities
would increase electricity prices, but could lead to a reduction in total bills
to participating customers (Hirst and Hadley, 1995), although the increased
electricity prices could deter companies from using these measures in a competitive
market. Parker (1995) indicated that DSM measures could lead to job creation
from production and installation of equipment.
9.2.10.3 Effects of Improvement in Energy Efficiency
Improvements in the efficiency of energy production may have substantial impacts
on households. Bashmakov (1993) reports a reduction in energy bills for end
users and a substantial reduction in environmental costs for Russia. The study
also reports that every rouble invested in energy efficiency generates 5 times
more jobs than investments in energy production. On the other hand, Gaj et
al. (1997) report a high social cost of economic transition caused by macroeconomic
reforms, which indirectly reduce GHG emissions, because employment in non-competitive
sectors is high in Poland.
|