10.2.4 Unilateral Participation
An extensive literature analyses the costs and sometimes the benefits of introducing
policies to control GHG emissions in a single country (Hoel, 1991; Bucholz and
Konrad, 1994; Porter and Van Linde, 1995; Hoel and Schneider, 1997; Endres and
Finus, 1998). Given the arguments proposed in the Introduction and the results
summarized in Section 10.3.1, this type of exercise
may seem unreasonable. There are, however, two main justifications for undertaking
it. The first is that domestic abatement costs (related to domestic policies
and measures) hardly depend on the coalition structure. Indeed, only if leakage
is large, and if climate policies have a large impact on trade and financial
flows, are the costs of domestic abatement policies significantly affected by
the size of the coalitions and by the agreed emission targets. Hence, it may
be useful to compute the costs of unilateral participation as a benchmark case,
which identifies costs that can be reduced only when coalition forms and the
Kyoto mechanisms are implemented among signatory countries. Notice the importance
of a careful assessment of leakage and of trade and financial repercussions
of climate policies (McKibbin et al., 1998). Notice also that the above
arguments concern the costs but not the benefits of climate policies. Indeed,
the climate benefits of unilateral participation are likely to be zero or almost
zero for all or almost all countries (a possible exception is the USA), given
the global nature of the climate problem (Hoel, 1991; Bucholz and Konrad, 1994;
Endres and Finus, 1998).
A second reason to assess the cost of a unilateral participation is that it
could identify a series of low cost (or no cost) options (so called low hanging
fruits or no regrets actions) that could be implemented independently of the
formation of a climate coalition. It could also help identify policy mixes that
help restructure the fiscal system and public regulatory and incentive schemes
in such a way that emission abatement costs are more than compensated by other
economic (non-environmental) benefits (the so-called double dividends)11.
There are also cases in which unilateral actions have been analyzed from a
very specific viewpoint. Examples are:
- Bucholz and Konrad (1994) analyze the detrimental effect of pre-negotiation
actions (more bargaining power can be achieved by unilaterally increasing
emissions before negotiating);
- Endres and Finus (1998) examine the negative effects on negotiations of
a higher environmental consciousness in one country;
- Hoel (1991) analyzes the costs of unilateral actions;
- Hoel and Schneider (1997) analyze the role of social norms; and
- Porter and Van Linde (1995) focus on the advantage of being a leader by
adopting emission reductions before the other countries.
|