10.4.4. Where Should the Response Take Place? The Relationship between Domestic
Mitigation and the Use of International Mechanisms
Inquiries into the options and costs to reduce GHGs, especially CO2,
emissions indicate that the costs of reductions vary substantially across sectors
in any given national economy and, perhaps even more significantly, across countries.
This implies that for uniformly mixing pollutants like GHGs the costs of achieving
any given level of environmental protection could be reduced if emission reductions
were undertaken at locations where the associated costs are lowest. The concept
has become known as where-flexibility in the climate policy literature.
An institutional setting is required to exploit the opportunities of where flexibility,
which involves a great variety of private and public decision-makers who originate
from different cultures, represent different constituencies (if any), and live
in systems with different social norms. Where-flexibility entails linkages both
to other international agreements (GATT, Second European Sulphur Protocol, etc.)
and to the legal systems of individual nations. As a result of its effects on
relative prices, the choice between the international or domestic strategy also
affects technological change.
In principle, two different mechanisms achieve where-flexibility: allowances
and credit baseline. In the case of allowances, each participant starts with
an initial endowment of pollution rights distributed by the government or through
an auction. Emission rights must cover each unit of emission. This system has
the character of emissions trading. Under a credit-baseline system, each participant
has a baseline (i.e., a counterfactual, hypothetical emission trend)
at the country, sector, or project level. Some measures are undertaken to reduce
emissions. The difference between the baseline and the factual emissions is
credited by an institutional body and can be traded. This system has the character
of emissions reduction production.
The Kyoto Protocol contains three instruments to make use of where-flexibility:
IET embodies the allowance system, while CDM and JI reflect the credit-baseline
system. The Kyoto Protocol on Iet allows Annex I parties with commitments listed
in Annex B to trade emission allowances during the commitment period. As for
JI, Article 6 declares that Annex I parties with commitments listed in Annex
B are allowed to transfer or acquire emission reduction units that result from
projects during the commitment period (the reduction units are specific to countries;
these parties have national baselines). Finally, CDM as defined in Article 12
implies that, starting in 2000, Annex I parties listed in Annex B are allowed
to acquire certified emission reductions from projects within the jurisdictions
of non-Annex I parties.
Three general principles operate behind these arrangements:
- first, voluntarism indicates the freedom of contracting, i.e., the
quantity-price combinations of exchange;
- second, supplementarity signifies the responsibility of Annex I parties
to fulfil part of their commitments within their own jurisdictions; and
- third, additionality means that projects in CDM and JI have to be additional
relative to the course of events in their absence (i.e., it must be
decided what would happen anyway and what constitutes an additional project).
Ample attention has been paid to formulate principles for the design of where-flexibility
instruments at the national and international level. The principles in the literature
(Michaelowa, 1995; Watt et al., 1995; Carter et al., 1996; Matsuo, 1998, Matsuo
et al., 1998; OECD, 1998; Ott, 1998; EC, 1999) include:
- Environmental effectiveness. All units traded should be backed by sound
data and verifiable emissions reductions; the use of the mechanisms is a means
to achieve emission commitments agreed under the Protocol and the mechanisms
should be designed to improve environmental performance and compliance with
these commitments.
- Economic efficiency. This includes the cost-effectiveness of the emission
reductions required by the Protocol, and over the longer term helping the
community of nations to address climate change in a least-cost manner. It
also requires the mechanisms to be administratively feasible, such that they
do not impose excessive transaction costs on market actors. Economic efficiency
will also improve if the market for trading and crediting is accessible to
a wide range of potential players.
- Equity. While the main issue of equity under the Kyoto Protocol is the determination
of assigned amounts or emission targets, the design of the implementation
mechanism must also be perceived as equitable. Implementation of the mechanisms
should not give an unfair advantage to any party or group of parties to the
disadvantage of others (procedural equity). It should also allow new entrants
over time.
- Credibility. Only a credible market mechanism should be used by the parties
and will be accepted by the public. A mechanism of low credibility might be
a source of various coalition formations at the negotiations and might undermine
the will to comply with the commitments.
In creating a regime for flexible instruments, perhaps the most important lesson
about multilateral agreements of the past two decades is that large and apparently
perfect constructions have rarely been implemented quickly. Quite
the contrary, the most successful examples of international regime building
are based on a piecemeal approach, that is the stepwise evolution
of political and legal mechanisms (Ott, 1998). For current DMFs, this might
lead to a strategy with several phases that bring together the national and
international levels at the speed of progress in international regime building
(Holtsmark and Hagem, 1998). This would involve a two-stage game for IET (Ott,
1998), with a twin cycle system for JI (Heller, 1995) that focuses
on the learning process in creating an international regime for JI.
There are some new and important factors to consider in the design of the instruments
(see Ott, 1998). The economic and ecological dimensions of climate change and
its mitigation affect different constituencies, sectors, and cultural values
of the parties. Stakeholders range from states and international organizations
to private companies and NGOs. Incentives motivate both private and governmental
participants to report the highest possible baselines of GHG emissions to secure
the largest amount of certified reduction credits. However, other processes
create the opposite incentives.
The implementation of these instruments can be seen as a further step towards
a more flexible and market-oriented policy in international environmental policy,
and as an extension of national instruments to the international level. At the
national level, some experience has already been accumulated with emissions
trading, such as the Emission Trading Program under the US Acid Rain Program,
the Los Angeles Regional Clean Air Incentives Markets, and the Norwegian Sulphur
Trading programme introduced in 1999. Actual experience is much thinner internationally.
Examples of the possibility for emission trading include the Montreal Protocol
intended to curb CFC emissions that deplete the ozone layer and the United Nations
Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE) Sulphur Protocol.
Many plausible arguments support the use of international mechanisms, as outlined
below.
Continues on next page
|