2.3 Greenhouse Gas Emissions: General Mitigation Scenarios
This chapter reviews three scenario literatures, which span a range from more
quantitative scenario analysis to analysis that is based more on narrative descriptions
(see Figure 2.1). At the quantitative end of the
spectrum are the general mitigation scenarios reviewed in this section,
which consist mainly of quantitative descriptions of driving forces and emission
profiles.
2.3.1 Overview of General Mitigation Scenarios
More than 500 emission scenarios have already been quantified, including non-mitigation
(non-intervention) scenarios and mitigation (intervention) scenarios that assume
policies to mitigate climate change. These scenarios have been published in
the literature or reported in conference proceedings, and many of them were
collected in the IPCC SRES database (Morita & Lee, 1998a) and made available
through the Internet (Morita & Lee, 1998b). Using this database, a systematic
review of non-mitigation scenarios has already been reported in the SRES (Nakicenovic
et al., 2000). However, several mitigation and other scenarios were missing
from this database and new emission scenarios have been quantified since the
SRES review. Accordingly, the missing scenarios and new scenarios were collected
and the database revised for this new review of mitigation scenarios (Rana and
Morita, 2000).
The current database collection, covered in this report, contains the results
of a total of 519 scenarios from 188 sources. These scenarios were mainly produced
after 1990. Two questionnaires were sent to representative modellers in the
world, and sets of scenarios from the International Energy Workshop (IEW) and
Energy Modelling Forum (EMF) comparison programmes were collected. The database
is intended to include only scenarios that are based on quantitative models.
Therefore, it does not include scenarios produced using other methods; for example,
heuristic estimations such as Delphi.
Of the 519 scenarios, a total of 380 were global GHG emission scenarios, most
of which were disaggregated into several regional emission profiles. Of these
380 global emission scenarios, a total of 150 were mitigation (climate policy)
scenarios. This review focuses on mitigation scenarios that cover global emissions
and also have a time horizon encompassing the coming century. Of the 150 mitigation
scenarios, a total of 126 long-term scenarios that cover the next 50 to 100
years were selected for this review. 24 scenarios were excluded on the basis
of their short time coverage.
Table 2.1 presents an outline of several representative
scenarios in this review; these scenarios exemplify the modelling literature.
Columns 1 and 2 of the table show the main identifiers of the scenarios, namely,
the model name and source and the policy scenario name, as given by the modellers.
The third and fourth columns show the policy scenario type and specific scenario
assumptions. The remaining columns contain additional important features of
the policy scenarios, including reduction time-paths and burden sharing, GHGs
analyzed, policy options and approaches, and feedback. Only five studies among
the selected sources of Table 2.1 have detailed policies.
Most of the other scenarios assume very simple policy options such as carbon
taxes and simple constraints.
Table 2.1: Overview of mitigation scenarios:
the main futures of representive scenarios from 26 sources |
|
Model name and source |
Policy scenario name
|
Policy scenario type
|
Specific scenario assumptions2
|
Reduction time paths and burden sharing
|
GHGs analyzed
|
Sectors in which policies are introduced
|
Feedbacks3
|
|
1 ASF |
RCWP
|
Emission stab.
|
475ppm
|
Based on policy scenario
|
CO2, CO, CH4, N2O
|
Detailed policy scenario
|
EP to M
|
EPA (1990) |
RCWR
|
Emission stab.
|
350ppm
|
|
NOx, CFCs
|
Energy supply; Land use; End use
|
EP to M
|
2 ASF/ IMAGE |
Control policy (2x CO2 by 2090)
|
Conc. stab.
|
540ppm
|
Based on policy scenario
|
CO2, CO, CH4, N2O
|
Detailed policy scenario |
EP to M
|
IPCC (1990) |
Accelerated control ( < 2x CO2)
|
Conc. stab.
|
465ppm
|
|
NOx, CFCs
|
Energy supply; Land use; End use |
|
3 ASF |
IS92b
|
Other mitigation1
|
18.6BtC
|
|
CO2, CO, CH4, N2O,
|
Energy supply; Industrial processes |
EP to M
|
IPCC (1992) |
|
|
(CO2 emissions)
|
|
VOC. SOx, CFCs, NOx
|
|
|
4 MESSAGE |
ECS92 + |
Other mitigation1
|
|
|
CO2
|
Energy supply; Industrial processes; |
|
Nakicenovic et al. (1993) |
|
|
|
|
|
End use |
|
5 DICE
Nordhaus (1994) |
Optimal policy; |
Other mitigation1 |
|
Utility maximization
|
CO2, CFCs
|
Energy |
C to M
|
10- yr delay of optimal policy |
Other mitigation1 |
|
Utility maximization
|
Other GHGs are
|
|
|
|
emission stabilization |
Emission stab. |
8BtC/ yr
(CO2 +CFCs) |
Based on policy scenario
|
|
|
I to M
|
|
20% emission cut |
Other mitigation1 |
6BtC/ yr
(CO2 +CFCs) |
Based on policy scenario
|
|
|
C to M
|
|
Geoengineering |
Other mitigation |
|
Based on policy scenario |
|
|
I to M
|
|
Climate stabilization |
Slow global temp. increase |
0.2° C/ decade |
Based on policy scenario |
|
|
|
6 CETA |
Selfish case |
Emissions cont. by OECD |
|
Cost minimization (regional) |
CO2, CO, CH4, N2O,
|
Energy |
C to M
|
Peck and Tiesberg (1995) |
Altruistic case |
Emissions cont. by OECD |
|
Cost minimization (global) |
CFCs
|
|
|
|
Optimal case |
Emissions cont. by both |
|
Cost minimization (global) |
|
|
|
7 LESS
(IPCC, 1996) |
LESS Constructions |
Other mitigation1 |
|
|
CO2
|
Energy supply |
|
8 Manne et al. (1995) |
Delayed tax; Early tax |
Other mitigation1 |
750 ppm; 540 ppm |
Utility maximization |
CO2, CH4, N2O
|
Energy |
C to M
|
MERGE |
Emission stab. |
Emission stab. |
540 ppm |
Utility maximization |
|
|
|
|
Conc. stab. |
Conc. stab. |
415 ppm |
Utility maximization |
|
|
|
9 MESSAGE |
Case C |
Other mitigation1 |
430 ppm |
Based on policy scenario |
CO2, CO, CH4, N2O,
|
Energy supply |
|
WEC (1995) |
Ecologically driven |
|
|
|
SOx, CFCs NOx, VOC.
|
End use |
|
10 WBGU (1995)
(German Adv. Council) |
Tolerable temp. window |
Safe corridor temp. rise constraint |
deltaT = 1° C (upper limit) |
Temp. rise constraint |
CO2
|
|
|
11 AIM/ Top- down |
Negotiable safe emiss. corridor |
Safe corridor |
deltaT = 1- 2° C |
Temp. rise constraint |
CO2
|
Energy |
EP to M
|
Matsuoka et al. (1996) |
|
Temperature rise const. |
|
|
|
|
|
12 DICE/ RICE |
Cooperative RICE |
Other mitigation1 |
|
Global welfare optimization |
CO2
|
Energy; Land use |
C to M
|
Nordhaus and Yang (1996) |
Non- cooperative RICE |
Other mitigation1 |
Regional welf. optimization |
|
|
|
I to M
|
13 IMAGE 2 |
Stab 350 650 ppm |
Conc. stab. |
367 564 ppm |
|
CO2, CH4, N2O
|
Energy supply; Industrial processes; |
|
Alcamo and Kreileman (1996) |
Stab yr 1990 |
Conc. stab. |
354 ppm |
|
|
Land use |
|
|
St2000-a - St2000-e |
Other mitigation1 |
633 433 ppm |
|
|
|
|
|
Safe emissions corridor |
Safe corridor |
deltaT = 1 2° C deg |
Temp. rise constraint |
|
|
|
14 MiniCAM |
Adv. tech |
Other mitigation1 |
|
Based on policy scenario |
CO2, CH4, N2O, SOx,
aerosols,
|
Energy supply |
EP to M
|
Edmonds et al. |
(5 Cases using different technologies) |
|
|
|
Halocarbons
|
|
|
15 YOHE
Yohe and
Wallace (1996) |
Stabilization |
Conc. stab. |
|
Based on policy scenario |
CO2
|
Energy |
C to M
|
16 DIAM
Ha- Duong, et al.
(1997) |
450A- D; 550A- D; 650A |
Conc. stab. |
|
Cost minimization |
CO2
|
Energy |
|
17 FUND 1.6 |
Non- cooperative optimum |
Other mitigation1 |
|
Regional welf. optimization |
CO2, CH4, N2O
|
|
|
Tol (1997) |
Cooperative optimum |
Other mitigation1 |
|
Generational
welf. optim. |
|
|
|
18 MERGE 3.0
Manne and Richels (1997) |
Range of scenarios
350 to 750 ppm |
Conc. stab. |
350 to 750ppm depending on scenario |
Utility maximization (non- Annex I begin limit in 2030) |
CO2
|
Energy |
C to M
|
19 SGM
Edmonds et al. (1997) |
M1990 ; M1990+ 10%; M1990 10%; M1995 |
Other mitigation1 |
|
|
CO2 , CO, CH2 , N2O,
NOx, VOC, SOx.
|
Energy |
EP to M
|
20 ABARE/ GTEM
Tulpule et al. (1998) |
Independent abatement; Annex B trading; Double bubble |
Other mitigation1 |
Kyoto targets |
|
CO2
|
Energy |
C to M
|
21 AIM/ Top- down
Kainuma et al. (1998) |
No trading; Annex I Trading; Global trading; Double bubble;
Annex I + Chn& Ind;
No trading 5% offset |
Other mitigation1 |
Kyoto targets |
Based on policy scenario |
|
|
C to M
|
22 G- CUBED |
Annex I trading; Double bubble |
Other mitigation1 |
|
|
CO2
|
Energy |
C to M
|
McKibbin (1998) |
Global permit trade |
|
|
|
|
|
|
23 MARIA |
Case B |
Emission stab. |
1990 level |
|
|
Energy supply; End use; Land use |
C to M
|
Mori and
Takahashi (1998) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
24 NE21 |
Conc. regulation |
Conc. stab. |
Below 550ppm |
Cost minimization |
CO2
|
Energy |
C to M
|
Fujii and Yamaji
(1998) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
25 WorldScan |
No Trade; Full trade; Clubs |
Other mitigation1 |
Kyoto targets |
|
CO2
|
|
EP to M
|
Bollen et al. (1996) |
Restricted trade; CDM |
|
|
|
|
|
|
26 FUND 1.6
Tol (1999) |
EMF- 14 scenarios
(WRE/ WGI+
450/ 550/ 650+ NC/ C) |
Conc. stab. |
Various |
Various |
|
|
|
|
Based on the type of mitigation, the scenarios can be classified into four
categories: concentration stabilization scenarios, emission stabilization scenarios,
safe emission corridor (tolerable windows/safe landing) scenarios, and other
mitigation scenarios.
Scenarios for concentration stabilization account for a large proportion of
the mitigation scenarios, with 47 of the 126 mitigation scenarios being classified
into this type. Many scenarios of this type were quantified in the process of
the EMF comparison (Weyant and Hill, 1999) where a systematic guideline was
prepared for stabilization quantification. Of the 47 scenarios, two-thirds are
intended to stabilize atmospheric concentrations of CO2 at 550ppmv.
The concentration of 550ppmv was used as a benchmark for stabilization in the
previous studies on mitigation scenarios. This number may be related to the
frequent references made to it in political discussions. The adoption by the
European Union of a maximum increase in global average temperature of 2°C
above pre-industrial levels is roughly equivalent to a stabilization level of
550ppmv CO2 equivalent or 450ppmv CO2. It does not imply
an agreed-upon desirability of stabilization at this level. In fact, environmental
groups have argued for desirable levels well below 550ppmv, while other interest
groups and some countries have questioned the necessity and/or feasibility of
achieving 550ppmv. Scenarios with levels of concentration stabilization other
than 550ppmv are contained in IPCC (1990), Manne et al. (1995), Alcamo and Kreileman
(1996), Ha-Duong et al. (1997), Manne and Richels (1997), and Fujii and Yamaji
(1998).
The emission stabilization scenarios account for 20 of the 126 mitigation scenarios.
Most scenarios of this type are intended to stabilize at 1990 emission levels
in Annex I or the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)
countries. Some scenarios have emissions stabilizing at other levels, for example,
the emissions stabilization scenario of DICE (Nordhaus, 1994) aims at a level
of 8GtC/yr of CO2 and chlorinated fluorocarbons (CFCs) by 2100. Other
stabilization scenarios, namely the Safe Emissions Corridor or Tolerable
Windows (WBGU, 1995; Alcamo and Kreileman, 1996; Matsuoka et al., 1996)
and Climate Stabilization (Nordhaus, 1994) scenarios, determine
the upper limit of emissions based on a constraint of some natural threshold,
such as global mean temperature increase rate. Only a few studies are based
on such scenarios.
Other scenarios based on DICE (Nordhaus, 1994), MERGE (Manne and Richels, 1997)
and MARIA (Mori and Takahashi, 1998) determine the level of emission reduction
based on net benefit maximization, which is estimated as the benefit produced
by climatic policy minus the policy implementation cost. In addition to the
above, the low CO2-emitting energy supply system (LESS) constructions
should be noted. These scenarios were developed on the basis of detailed assessments
of technological potentials, and can therefore be distinguished from many other
mitigation scenarios (see Box 2.2).
Box 2.2. Review of Low Carbon Dioxide Emitting Energy Supply System
(LESS) Constructions from the Second Assessment Report
The LESS constructions described in the IPCCs SAR, Working Group
II (IPCC, 1996, Ch19), were probably the only constructions akin to mitigation
scenarios taken up in SAR. They are similar to the mitigation
scenarios reviewed in this chapter in that they also explore alternative
paths to energy futures in order to achieve mitigation of carbon dioxide.
A number of technologies with potential for reducing CO2 emissions
exist or are in a state of possible commercialization. The LESS constructions
illustrate the potential for reducing emissions by using energy more efficiently
and by using various combinations of low CO2-emitting energy
supply technologies, including shifts to low-carbon fossil fuels, shifts
to renewable and nuclear energy sources, and decarbonization of fuels.
The assumed technological feasibility and costs of each of the technologies
included in these variants is based on an extensive literature review.
Both bottom-up and top-down approaches were used in the LESS constructions.
For the reference cases in the bottom-up analyses, the energy demand projections
for the high economic growth variant of the Accelerated Policies
scenarios developed by the Response Strategies Working Group (RSWG, 1990)
were adopted.
The five variants constructed in the bottom-up analyses were (1) BI:
biomass intensive, (2) NI: nuclear intensive, (3) NGI: natural gas intensive,
(4) CI: coal intensive, and (5) HD: high demand. The BI variant explores
the potential for using renewable electricity sources in power generation.
Both intermittent renewables (wind, photovoltaics, and solar thermal-electricity
technologies) and advanced biomass electricity-generating technologies
(biomass-integrated gasifier and/or gas turbine technologies through 2025
and biomass-integrated gasifier and/or fuel-cell technologies through
2050 and beyond) were applied. The NI variant involves a revitalization
of the nuclear energy option and deployment of nuclear electric power
technology worldwide. In the NGI variant, the emphasis is on natural gas.
Any natural gas in excess of that for the reference cases is used to make
methanol (CH4O) and hydrogen (H2). These displace
CH4O and H2 produced from plantation biomass. In
the CI variant, the strategy for achieving deep reductions involves using
coal and biomass for CH4O and H2 production, along
with sequestration of the CO2 separated out at synthetic fuel
production facilities. Finally, in the HD variant the excess demand is
met by providing an extra supply of fuels with low emissions. To illustrate
the possibilities, the HD variant is constructed with all of the incremental
electricity provided by intermittent renewables.
A top-down exercise was carried out to test the robustness of the bottom-up
energy supply analyses by incorporating performance and cost parameters
for some of the key technologies in the BI variant. Six technology cases
were modelled using the EdmondsReillyBarns (ERB) model. The
results for CO2 emissions in two cases (cases 5 and 6) were
comparable to the bottom-up LESS variants, but the energy end-uses were
different owing to different assumptions.
The central finding of the LESS construction exercise is that deep reductions
of CO2 emissions from the energy sector are technically possible
within 50 to 100 years, using alternative strategies. Global CO2
emissions could be reduced from about 6GtC in 1990 to about 2GtC in 2100,
in many combinations of the options analyzed. Cumulative CO2
emissions, from 1990 to 2100, would range from about 450 to about 470GtC
in the alternative LESS constructions. Higher energy efficiency is underscored
in order to achieve deep reductions in CO2 emissions, increase
the flexibility of supply-side combinations, and reduce overall energy
system costs.
|
Of the remaining mitigation scenarios, a total of 50 adopt other criteria to
reduce GHGs. Some of these scenarios assume the introduction of specific policies
such as a constant carbon tax, while others assume the Kyoto Protocol targets
for Annex I countries up to 2010 and a stabilization of their emissions thereafter
at 2010 levels.
While all the scenarios deal necessarily with energy-related CO2
emissions that have the most significant influence on climate change, several
models include CO2 emissions from land use changes and industrial
processes (e.g., IPCC, 1992; Nakicenovic et al., 1993; Matsuoka et al., 1995;
Alcamo and Kreileman, 1996). Some of them include other important GHGs in their
calculations, such as methane (CH4) and nitrous oxide (N2O)
(e.g., EPA, 1990; IPCC, 1990; Manne et al., 1995; Tol, 1997), and a few go even
further to include sulphates, volatile organic compounds (VOCs), and halocarbons
(e.g. IPCC, 1992; WEC, 1995; Edmonds et al., 1996, 1997). With respect to the
policy options used in the scenario quantifications, three fields are taken
into account in the reviewed studies: energy systems (including both supply
and demand), industrial processes (including cement and metal production), and
land use (including agriculture and forest management).
Since most of the modelling exercises have been carried out to study the CO2
emissions from human activities linked to the use of energy, energy supply and
end-use are naturally the areas where policy is applied. Energy supply options
include natural gas, renewable energy, and commercial biomass; introduction
of new technologies; and so on. End-use options chiefly pertain to increased
energy efficiency in industry, transport, and residential and/or commercial
applications.
The policy instruments analyzed depend on the underlying model structure. Most
of the scenarios introduce policies such as simple carbon taxes or a constraint
on emissions or concentration levels for achieving the desired reduction or
stabilization. How the constraint is imposed varies from scenario to scenario.
Among the models with regional disaggregation, a few regional targets have been
introduced (e.g., Nordhaus, 1994; Tol, 1999). Regional disaggregation also allows
modellers to let the regions trade in emission permits. Permit trading is introduced
in more recent work, especially just before and after the Third Conference of
the Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change in
Kyoto (December 1997). Some studies offer permit trading as a mechanism to reduce
the overall costs of abatement. Much of the work done in the early 1990s led
to the development of detailed scenarios for introducing such policies (EPA,
1990; IPCC, 1990, 1992). Some models employ policies of supply-side technology
introduction (Nakicenovic et al., 1993; Edmonds et al., 1996; Fujii and Yamaji,
1998), while other models emphasize the introduction of efficient demand-side
technology (EPA, 1990; Kainuma et al., 1999a).
The issue of burden sharing among regions is a contentious one and it was sparsely
treated in the first half of the 1990s. Most discussions about burden sharing
are of a qualitative and partial nature and are not related to model-based mitigation
scenarios. A few studies (most notably Rose and Stevens, 1993; Enquete Commission,
1995; and Manne and Richels, 1997) present a set of burden-sharing rules in
their scenarios. Of late, the EMF exercises looking at the Kyoto scenarios have
treated this issue better than in the past (Weyant, 1999).
The time-paths of emission reduction are determined in three ways in the reviewed
studies. First, the emission trajectories are determined by policy scenarios
that have been designed in detail for regions over the time frame (EPA, 1990;
IPCC, 1990; WEC, 1995; Edmonds et al., 1996; Yohe and Wallace, 1996; Kainuma
et al., 1998). Second, dynamic optimization models automatically determine these
reduction time-paths by global cost minimization over time (e.g., Peck and Tiesberg,
1995; Fujii and Yamaji, 1998) or economic welfare maximization (Nordhaus, 1994;
Manne et al., 1995). Third, mitigation scenarios of tolerable windows/safe landing,
or safe emission corridors, can fix the time series of emission reduction by
introducing a specific constraint of the rate of change in natural systems including
the global temperature change rate (e.g., Alcamo and Kreileman, 1996).
Finally, there are differences in the treatment of feedback to the macro-economy
in the models. While most bottom-up models have no feedback from cost to the
macro-economy, top-down models allow for the feedback of energy prices to the
macro-economy. The MERGE (Manne et al., 1995) and CETA (Peck and Tiesberg, 1995)
models also have feedback from impacts to the macro-economy.
Technological improvement is a critical element in all the general mitigation
scenarios. This is apparent when the detailed policy options are studied, where
such literature is available. For instance, Nakicenovic et al. (1993) (using
MESSAGE) incorporated policies of dematerialization and recycling, efficiency
improvements and industrial process changes, and fuel-mix changes in the industrial
sector; fuel efficiency improvements, modal split changes, behavioural change,
and technological change in the transport sector; and efficiency improvements
of end-use conversion technologies, fuel-mix changes, and demand-side measures
in the household and services sector. It should be noted that efficiency improvement
through technological advancement is emphasized in all sectors. Similar policies
leading to efficiency improvement were also underlined in earlier modelling
studies such as EPA (1990), IPCC (1990), and IPCC (1992).
|