2.5.2 Review of Post-SRES Mitigation Scenarios
2.5.2.1 Background and Outline of Post-SRES Analysis
The review of general mitigation scenarios shows that mitigation scenarios
and policies are strongly related to their baselines, and that there has been
no systematic comparison of the relationship between baseline and mitigation
scenarios. Modellers participating in the SRES process recognized the need to
analyze and compare mitigation scenarios using as their baselines the new IPCC
scenarios, which quantify a wide range of future worlds. Consequently, they
participated (on a voluntary basis) in a special comparison programme to quantify
SRES-based mitigation scenarios (Morita et al., 2000a; 2000b). These SRES-based
scenarios are called Post-SRES Mitigation Scenarios.
The process of the post-SRES analysis was started by a public invitation to
modellers. A Call for Scenarios was sent to more than one hundred
researchers in March 1999 by the Co-ordinating Lead Authors of this chapter
and the SRES to facilitate an assessment of the potential implications of mitigation
scenarios based on the SRES cases, which report was developed in support of
the Third Assessment Report. Modellers from around the world were invited to
prepare quantified stabilization scenarios for two or more concentrations of
atmospheric CO2, based on one or more of the six SRES scenarios.
Concentration ceilings include 450, 550 (minimum requirement), 650, and 750ppmv,
and harmonization with the SRES scenarios was required by tuning reference cases
to SRES values for GDP, population, and final energy demand.
Nine modelling teams participated in the comparison programme, including six
SRES modelling teams and three other teams: AIM team (Jiang et al., 2000), ASF
team (Sankovski et al., 2000), IMAGE team, LDNE team (Yamaji et al., 2000),
MESSAGE-MACRO team (Riahi & Roehrl, 2000), MARIA team (Mori, 2000), MiniCAM
team (Pitcher, 2000), PETRO team (Kverndokk et al., 2000) and WorldScan team
(Bollen et al., 2000). Table 2.6 shows all the modelling
teams and the stabilized concentration levels which were adopted as stabilization
targets by each one. Most of the modelling teams covered more than two SRES
baseline scenarios, and half of them developed multiple stabilization cases
for at least one baseline, so that a systematic review can be conducted to clarify
the relationship between baseline scenarios and mitigation policies and/or technologies.
While all baselines were analyzed, the A1B baseline was most frequently used.
Across baselines, the stabilization target of 550ppmv seemed to be the most
popular. Because of time constraints involved in quantifying the stabilization
scenarios, the modelling teams mostly focused their analyses on energy-related
CO2 emissions. However, about half of the modelling teams, notably
the AIM, IMAGE, MARIA, and MiniCAM teams, have quantified mitigation scenarios
in non-energy CO2 emissions as well as in non-CO2 emissions.
The modelling teams that did not estimate non-energy CO2 emissions
introduced scenarios of them from outside of their models for estimating atmospheric
concentrations of CO2.
In order to check the performance of CO2 concentration stabilization
for each post-SRES mitigation scenario, a special generator (Matsuoka,
2000) was used by the modelling teams to convert the CO2 emissions
into CO2 concentration trajectories. In addition, the generator was
used by them to estimate the eventual level of atmospheric CO2 concentration
by 2300, based on the 1990 to 2100 CO2 emissions trajectories from
the scenarios. This generator is based on the Bern Carbon Cycle Model (Joos
et al., 1996), which was used in the IPCC SAR (IPCC, 1996) and TAR (IPCC, 2001).
Using this generator, each modelling team adjusted their mitigation scenarios
so that the interpolated CO2 concentration reached one of the alternative
fixed target levels at the year 2150 within a 5% error. The year 2150 was selected
based on Enting et al. (1994) who gave a basis for stabilization scenarios of
the IPCC SAR (IPCC, 1996).13
A further constraint imposed was that the interpolated emission curve should
be smooth after 2100, the end of the time-horizon of the scenarios. This adjustment
played an important role in the post-SRES analyses for harmonizing emissions
concentrations levels across the stabilization scenarios. The key driving forces
of emissions such as population, GDP, and final energy consumption were harmonized
in baseline assumptions specified by the six SRES scenarios.
Table 2.6: Post-SRES participants and
quantified scenarios (indicated by CO2 stabilization target in
ppmv) |
|
Baseline scenarios |
A1B
|
A1FI
|
A1T
|
A2
|
B1
|
B2
|
|
AIM
(NIES and Kyoto University, Japan) |
450, 550,
650
|
550
|
|
550
|
550
|
550
|
ASF (ICF Corporation, USA) |
|
|
|
550, 750
|
|
|
IMAGE (RIVM, Netherlands) |
550
|
|
|
|
450
|
|
LDNE (Tokyo University, Japan) |
550
|
550
|
550
|
550
|
550
|
550
|
MARIA (Science University of Tokyo,
Japan) |
450, 550,
650
|
|
450, 550,
650
|
|
450, 550
|
450, 550,
650
|
MESSAGE-MACRO
(IIASA, Austria) |
450, 550,
650
|
450(*),550(*),
650(*), 750(*)
|
450, 550
|
550, 750
|
|
550
|
MiniCAM (PNNL, USA) |
550 (*)
|
450, 550,
650, 750
|
|
550
|
450, 550
|
550(*)
|
PETRO
(Statistics Norway, Norway) |
450, 550,
650, 750
|
|
450, 550,
650, 750
|
|
|
|
WorldScan (CPB, Netherlands) |
450(**),
550(**)
|
|
|
450,
550(**)
|
450(**),
550
|
450(**),
550
|
|
|
2.5.2.2 Storylines of Post-SRES Mitigation Scenarios
The procedure for creating post-SRES mitigation scenarios was similar to the
SRES process, even though the period for the post-SRES work was much shorter
than that for the SRES and, in contrast to the SRES process, the exercise was
voluntary and not mandated by the IPCC. The storyline approach of SRES indicates
that different future worlds will have different mitigative capacities (cf.
Section 1.5.1). Hence, the first step of the post-SRES
scenario work was to create storylines for the mitigation scenarios.
In general, mitigation scenarios are defined relative to a baseline scenario.
If mitigation strategies are formulated and implemented in any of the future
worlds as described within SRES, a variety of aspects of that world will determine
the capacity to formulate and implement carbon reduction policies, for instance:
- The availability and dissemination of relevant knowledge on emissions and
climate change;
- The institutional, legal, and financial infrastructure to implement mitigation
policies and measures;
- Entrepreneurial and/or governmental policies for generating innovation
and encouraging the penetration of new technologies; and
- The mechanisms by which consumers and entrepreneurs respond to changing
prices and new products and processes.
In the post-SRES process, it was difficult for the modelling teams to consider
all of these aspects with relation to the SRES future worlds, because of their
inherent complexity and the amount of time available for the work. However,
some aspects were considered by some modelling teams and these were reflected
in the quantification assumptions. The rest of this section illustrates these
major points in the form of storylines for each of the six SRES scenarios, which
describe the relationship between the kind of future world on the one hand and
the capacity for mitigation on the other.
The A1 world is well equipped to formulate and implement mitigation strategies
in view of its high-tech, high-growth orientation and its willingness to co-operate
at a global scale, provided the major actors acknowledge the need for mitigation.
There will be good monitoring and reporting on emissions and climate change,
and possible signs of climate change will be detected early and become part
of the international agenda. Market-oriented policies and measures will be the
preferred response. Least-cost options will be searched for and implemented
through international negotiation and mechanisms with the support of governments
and multinational companies. New emission reduction technologies from developed
countries will enable developing countries to respond more rapidly and effectively
if barriers to technology transfer can be overcome. In this high-growth world,
the economic costs associated with the response to climate change are likely
to be bearable. In the A1B scenario, where mitigation strategies may hit the
limits of renewable energy supply, and in the A1FI scenario, carbon removal
and storage as well as higher end-use energy efficiency will become major emission
reduction options. In the A1T scenario, technology developments are such that
mitigation policies and measures only require limited additional efforts.
Developing and implementing climate change mitigation measures and policies
in the A2 world can be quite complicated. This is a result of several features
embedded in the scenario storyline: rapid population growth, relatively slow
GDP per capita growth, slow technological progress, and a regional and partially
isolationist approach in national and international politics. Because
of all these serious challenges, the abatement of GHG emissions in the A2 world
becomes plausible only in the situation when the negative effects of climate
change become imminent and the associated losses outweigh the costs
of mitigation. The same features that make the A2 world non-receptive
to worldwide mitigation policies may exacerbate the climate change effects and
prompt nations to act. Measures such as a rapid shift towards high-tech renewable
energy or deep-sea carbon storage will be highly improbable in the A2 world
as a consequence of technology limitations. Instead, such relatively low-tech
measures as limiting energy consumption, and capturing and using methane from
natural gas systems, coal mining, and landfills better fit the A2 worlds
economic and technological profile. The lack of global co-operation may cause
rather large regional variations in the feasibility and cost of mitigation policies
and measures.
The B1 world is also well equipped to formulate and implement mitigation strategies,
in view of its high economic growth and willingness to co-operate at a global
scale. In comparison with the A1 world, however, it will be confronted with
higher marginal abatement costs, although total costs are much lower than in
A1B or A1FI. This is because baseline carbon emissions are lower in the B1 world
compared to the A1 world, a consequence of the emphasis on sustainable development
in B1. There will be intense monitoring and reporting of emissions and climate
change. The precautionary principle informs international agenda setting and
policy formulation, with governments taking responsibility for climate change-related
preventive and adaptive action. Tightening international standards generates
incentives for further innovation towards energy-efficiency and low- and zero-carbon
options. Educational campaigns are another important instrument. Developed regions
support the less developed regions in a variety of ways, including transfer
of energy-efficiency and renewable-energy related technologies. Carbon taxes
are introduced; an elaborate phase-in mechanism for less developed regions is
negotiated and implemented. A part of the carbon tax revenue is used to compensate
some fossil-fuel exporters and for a fund to compensate those affected by climate
change.
In the B2 scenario actions to reduce GHG emissions are taken mainly at a local
or regional scale in response to climate change impacts. Environmentally aware
citizens of the B2 world will increasingly attribute damages to human-induced
climate change. High-income countries, which are generally less vulnerable to
climate change impacts, will increasingly see the need for climate policy action
as a consequence of cost-benefit analyses. With increasing costs of damage,
counter-measures challenge existing energy sector policies and institutional
frameworks. Generally high educational levels promote both development and environmental
protection. Resource availability, economic development, and technical change
are uneven over regions. In relative terms, R&D expenditures are expected
to stay constant, but they will be more targeted towards cleaner and less carbon-intensive
energy technologies. Existing bilateral trade links will foster bilateral technology
transfer from OECD countries to some developing countries. This is because rapidly
increasing energy and, in particular, electricity demand in developing countries
present business opportunities no longer available in OECD countries. Therefore,
there exist a number of incentives for bilateral environmental policy co-operation
between R&D intensive countries in the North and developing countries of
the South. Energy trade links, first for oil and later for natural gas and methanol,
will play an important seed role for new environmental bilateral co-operation,
leading to a regionally heterogeneous approach to GHG reduction.
|