3.2 Drivers of Technological Change and Innovation
Reduction of greenhouse gas emissions is highly dependent upon both technological
innovation and practices. The rate of introduction of new technologies, and
the drivers for adoption are, however, different in industrial market economies,
economies in transition and developing countries.
In industrial countries, technologies are developed as a result of corporate
innovation or government-supported R&D, and in response to environmental
regulations, energy tax policies, or other incentives. The shift of electric
and gas utilities from regulated monopolies to competing enterprises has also
played a major role in the strong shift to combined cycle gas turbines, often
with utilization of the waste heat in the electric power sector.
Figure 3.3: Total net resource flows to aid recipient countries.
|
The most rapid growth in the electric power sector and many energy intensive
industries is now occurring in developing countries, which have come to rely
heavily upon technology transfer for investments in energy infrastructure. Capital
for investment flows from industrial countries to developing countries through
several pathways such as multilateral and bilateral official development assistance
(ODA), foreign direct investments (FDI), commercial sales, and commercial and
development bank lending. During the period 1993 to 1997, ODA experienced a
downward trend with an increase in 1998, while FDI has increased substantially
by a factor of five (see Figure 3.3) (OECD, 1999; Metz
et al., 2000). This shift is a consequence of the many opportunities that have
opened for private capital in developing countries, and a reluctance by some
industrial countries to increase ODA. The energy supply sector of developing
countries is also undergoing deregulation from state to private ownership, increasing
the role of the private sector in technology innovation.
A large percentage of capital is invested in a relatively small number of technologies
that are responsible for a significant share of the energy supply and consumption
market (automobiles, electric power generators, and building heating and cooling
systems). There is a tendency to optimize these few technologies and their related
infrastructure development, gaining them advantages that will make it more difficult
for subsequent competing technologies to catch up. For example, a particular
technological configuration such as road-based automobiles can become locked-in
as the dominant transportation mode. This occurs because evolution of technological
systems is as important as the evolution of individual new technologies. As
their use expands their development becomes intertwined with the evolution of
many other technologies and institutional and social developments. The evolution
of technologies for oil exploration and extraction and for automobile production
both affect and are affected by the expansion of infrastructures such as efficient
refineries and road networks. They also affect and are affected by social and
institutional developments, such as political and military power and settlement
patterns, and business adaptation to changed transportation options, respectively.
Lock-in effects have two implications. First, early investments and early applications
are extremely important in determining which technologies will be most important
in the future. Second, learning and lock-in make technology transfer more difficult.
Learning is much more dependent on successful building and using technology
than on instruction manuals. Furthermore, technological productivity is strongly
dependent upon complementary networks of suppliers, repair persons and training
which is difficult to replicate in another country or region (IIASA/WEC, 1998;
Unruh, 1999, 2000).
There are multiple government-driven pathways for technological innovation
and change. Through regulation of energy markets, environmental regulations,
energy efficiency standards, and market-based initiatives such as energy and
emission taxes, governments can induce technology changes and influence the
level of innovations. Important examples of government policies on energy supply
include the Clean Air Act in the USA, the Non Fossil Fuel Obligation in the
UK, the Feed-in-Law in Germany, the Alcohol Transport Fuel Program in Brazil,
and utility deregulation that began in the UK and has now moved to the USA,
Norway, Argentina, and many other countries. Voluntary agreements or initiatives
implemented by the manufacturing industry, including energy supply sections,
can also be drivers of technological change and innovation.
In the energy-consuming sector, major government actions can promote energy
efficient use and the replacement of high (like coal) to lower carbon fuels
(like natural gas and renewables). Energy efficiency standards for vehicles,
appliances, heating and cooling systems, and buildings can also substantially
encourage the adoption of new technologies. On the other hand, continued subsidies
for coal and electricity, and a failure to properly meter electricity and gas
are substantial disincentives to energy efficiency gains and the uptake of renewable
and low carbon technologies. Government-supported R&D has also played a
significant role in developing nuclear power, low carbon technologies such as
gas turbines, and carbon-free energy sources including wind, solar, and other
renewables. Such government actions in the energy-consuming sector can ensure
increasing access to energy required for sustainable development.
While regulation in national energy markets is well established, it is unclear
how international efforts at GHG emission regulation may be applied at the global
level. The Kyoto Protocol and its mechanisms represent opportunities to bring
much needed energy-efficient practices and alternative energy to the continuously
growing market of developing countries and in reshaping the energy markets of
the economies in transition.
Important dimensions and drivers for the successful transfer of lower GHG technologies
to developing countries and economies in transition are capacity building, an
enabling environment, and adequate mechanisms for technology transfer (Metz
et al., 2000). Markets for the use of new forms of energy are often non-existent
or very small, and require collaboration among the local government and commercial
or multilateral lending banks to promote procurement. It may also be necessary
to utilize temporary subsidies and market-based incentives as well. Because
energy is such a critical driver of development, it is essential that strategies
to reduce GHG emissions be consistent with development goals. This is true for
all economies, but is especially true for developing countries and economies
in transition where leap-frogging to modern, low emitting, highly efficient
technologies is critical (Moomaw et al., 1999a; Goldemberg, 1998).
Non-energy benefits are an important driver of technological change and innovation
(Mills and Rosenfeld, 1996; Pye and McKane, 2000). Certain energy-efficient,
renewable, and distributed energy options offer non-energy benefits. One class
of such benefits accrues at the national level, e.g. via improved competitiveness,
energy security, job creation, environmental protection, while another relates
to consumers and their decision-making processes. From a consumer perspective,
it is often the non-energy benefits that motivate decisions to adopt such technologies.
Consumer benefits from energy-efficient technologies can be grouped into the
following categories: (1) improved indoor environment, comfort, health, safety,
and productivity; (2) reduced noise; (3) labour and time savings; (4) improved
process control; (5) increased reliability, amenity or convenience; (6) water
savings and waste minimization; and (7) direct and indirect economic benefits
from downsizing or elimination of equipment. Such benefits have been observed
in all end-use sectors. For renewable and distributed energy technologies, the
non-energy benefits stem primarily from reduced risk of business interruption
during and after natural disasters, grid system failures or other adverse events
in the electric power grid (Deering and Thornton, 1998).
Product manufacturers often emphasize non-energy benefits as a driver in their
markets, e.g. the noise- and UV-reduction benefits of multi-glazed window systems
or the disaster-recovery benefits of stand-alone photovoltaic technologies.
Of particular interest are attributes of energy-efficient and renewable energy
technologies and practices that reduce insurance risks (Mills and Rosenfeld,
1996). Approximately 80 specific examples have been identified with applications
in the buildings and industrial sectors (Vine et al., 1998), and insurers have
begun to promote these in the buildings sector (Mills, 1999). The insurance
sector has also supported transportation energy efficiency improvements that
increase highway safety (reduced speed limits) and urban air quality (mass transportation)
(American Insurance Association, 1999). Insurance industry concern about increased
natural disasters caused by global climate change also serves as a motivation
for innovative market transformation initiatives on behalf of the industry to
support climate change adaptation and mitigation (Mills 1998, 1999; Vellinga
et al., 2000; Nutter, 1996). Market benefits for industries that adopt low carbon-
emitting processes and products have also been increasingly recognized and documented
(Hawken et al., 1999; Romm, 1999).
|