10.3 Linkages to National and Local Sustainable Development
Choices
Much of the ambiguity related to sustainable development and climate change
arises from the lack of measurements that could provide policymakers with essential
information on the alternative choices at stake, how those choices affect clear
and recognizable social, economic, and environmental critical issues, and also
provide a basis for evaluating their performance in achieving goals and targets.
Therefore, indicators are indispensable to make the concept of sustainable development
operational. At the national level important steps in the direction of defining
and designing different sets of indicators have been undertaken; however, much
work remains to be done to translate sustainability objectives into practical
terms.
It is difficult to generalize about sustainable development policies and choices.
Sustainability implies and requires diversity, flexibility, and innovation.
Policy choices are meant to introduce changes in technological patterns of natural
resource use, production and consumption, structural changes in the production
systems, spatial distribution of population and economic activities, and behavioural
patterns. Climate change literature has by and large addressed the first three
topics, while the relevance of choices and decisions related to behavioural
patterns and lifestyles has been paid scant attention. Consumption patterns
in the industrialized countries are an important reason for climate change.
If people changed their preferences this could alleviate climate change considerably.
To change consumption patterns, however, people must not only change their behaviour
but also change themselves because these patterns are an essential element of
lifestyles and, therefore, of self-esteem. Yet, apart from climate change there
are other reasons to do so as well as indications that this change can be fostered
politically.
A critical requirement of sustainable development is a capacity to design policy
measures that, without hindering development and consistent with national strategies,
could exploit potential synergies between national economic growth objectives
and environmentally focused policies. Climate change mitigation strategies offer
a clear example of how co-ordinated and harmonized policies can take advantage
of the synergies between the implementation of mitigation options and broader
objectives. Energy efficiency improvements, including energy conservation, switch
to low carbon content fuels, use of renewable energy sources and the introduction
of more advanced non conventional energy technologies, are expected to have
significant impacts on curbing actual GHG emission tendencies. Similarly, the
adoption of new technologies and practices in agriculture and forestry activities
as well as the adoption of clean production processes could make substantial
contributions to the GHG mitigation effort. Depending on the specific context
in which they are applied, these options may entail positive side effects or
double dividends, which in some cases are worth undertaking whether or not there
are climate-related reasons for doing so.
Sustainable development requires radical technological and related changes
in both developed and developing countries. Technological innovation and the
rapid and widespread transfer and implementation of individual technological
options and choices, as well as overall technological systems, constitute major
elements of global strategies to achieve both climate stabilization and sustainable
development. However, technology transfer requires more than technology itself.
An enabling environment for the successful transfer and implementation of technology
plays a crucial role, particularly in developing countries. If technology transfer
is to bring about economic and social benefits it must take into account the
local cultural traditions and capacities as well as the institutional and organizational
circumstances required to handle, operate, replicate, and improve the technology
on a continuous basis.
The process of integrating and internalizing climate change and sustainable
development policies into national development agendas requires new problem
solving strategies and decision-making approaches. This task implies a twofold
effort. On one hand, sustainable development discourse needs greater analytical
and intellectual rigor (methods, indicators, etc.) to make this concept advance
from theory to practice. On the other hand, climate change discourse needs to
be aware of both the restrictive set of assumptions underlying the tools and
methods applied in the analysis, and the social and political implications of
scientific constructions of climate change. Over recent years a good deal of
analytical work has addressed the problem in both directions. Various approaches
have been explored to transcend the limits of the standard views and decision
frameworks in dealing with issues of uncertainty, complexity, and the contextual
influences of human valuation and decision making. A common theme emerges: the
emphasis on participatory decision making frameworks for articulating new institutional
arrangements.
10.4 Key Policy-relevant Scientific Questions
Different levels of globally agreed limits for climate change (or for corresponding
atmospheric GHG concentrations), entail different balances of mitigation costs
and net damages for individual nations. Considering the uncertainties involved
and future learning, climate stabilization will inevitably be an iterative process:
nation states determine their own national targets based on their own exposure
and their sensitivity to other countries' exposure to climate change. The
global target emerges from consolidating national targets, possibly involving
side payments, in global negotiations. Simultaneously, agreement on burden sharing
and the agreed global target determines national costs. Compared to the expected
net damages associated with the global target, nation states might reconsider
their own national targets, especially as new information becomes available
on global and regional patterns and impacts of climate change. This is then
the starting point for the next round of negotiations. It follows from the above
that establishing the "magic number" (i.e., the upper limit for global
climate change or GHG concentration in the atmosphere) will be a long process
and its source will primarily be the policy process, hopefully helped by improving
science.
Looking at the key dilemmas in climate change decision making, the following
conclusions emerge (see also Table TS.7):
- a carefully crafted portfolio of mitigation, adaptation, and learning activities
appears to be appropriate over the next few decades to hedge against the risk
of intolerable magnitudes and/or rates of climate change (impact side) and
against the need to undertake painfully drastic emission reductions if the
resolution of uncertainties reveals that climate change and its impacts might
imply high risks;
- emission reduction is an important form of mitigation, but the mitigation
portfolio includes a broad range of other activities, including investments
to develop low-cost non-carbon, energy efficient and carbon management technologies
that will make future CO2 mitigation less expensive;
- timing and composition of mitigation measures (investment into technological
development or immediate emission reductions) is highly controversial because
of the technological features of energy systems, and the range of uncertainties
involved in the impacts of different emission paths;
- international flexibility instruments help reduce the costs of emission
reductions, but they raise a series of implementation and verification issues
that need to be balanced against the cost savings;
- while there is a broad consensus to use the Pareto optimality30
as the efficiency principle, there is no agreement on the best equity principle
on wich to build an equitable international regime. Efficiency and equity
are important concerns in negotiating emission limitation schemes, and they
are not mutually exclusive. Therefore, equity will play an important role
in determining the distribution of emissions allowances and/or within compensation
schemes following emission trading that could lead to a disproportionately
high level of burden on certain countries. Finally, it could be more important
to build a regime on the combined implications of the various equity principles
rather than to select any one particular equity principle. Diffusing non-carbon,
energy-efficient, as well as other GHG reducing technologies worldwide could
make a significant contribution to reducing emissions over the short term,
but many barriers hamper technology transfer, including market imperfections,
political problems, and the often-neglected transaction costs;
- some obvious linkages exist between current global and continental environmental
problems and attempts of the international community to resolve them, but
the potential synergies of jointly tackling several of them have not yet been
thoroughly explored, let alone exploited.
Mitigation and adaptation decisions related to anthropogenically induced climate
change differ. Mitigation decisions involve many countries, disperse benefits
globally over decades to centuries (with some near-term ancillary benefits),
are driven by public policy action, based on information available today, and
the relevant regulation will require rigorous enforcement. In contrast, adaptation
decisions involve a shorter time span between outlays and returns, related costs
and benefits accrue locally, and their implementation involves local public
policies and private adaptation of the affected social agents, both based on
improving information. Local mitigation and adaptive capacities vary significantly
across regions and over time. A portfolio of mitigation and adaptation policies
will depend on local or national priorities and preferred approaches in combination
with international responsibilities.
Given the large uncertainties characterizing each component of the climate
change problem, it is difficult for decision makers to establish a globally
acceptable level of stabilizing GHG concentrations today. Studies appraised
in Chapter10
support the obvious expectations that lower stabilization targets involve substantially
higher mitigation costs and relatively more ambitious near-term emission reductions
on the one hand, but, as reported by WGII, lower targets induce significantly
smaller bio/geophysical impacts and thus induce smaller damages and adaptation
costs.
|