1.5.2. Socioeconomic Uncertainties
An often overlooked source of uncertainty in assessments of impacts and vulnerability
is the wide difference in assumptions (often not even stated) in the initial
conditions and trends of environmental systems and socioeconomic conditions.
These assumptions include information on population and related variables (e.g.,
population density), economic trends (e.g., income levels, sectoral composition
of GDP, or levels of trade), other social indicators (e.g., education levels,
private- and public-sector institutions), culture, land cover and use, and availability
and use of other resources such as water. They are important not only for determining
the forces driving global changes but also for understanding the general capabilities
available to societies for adaptation. Projections of these factors for time
periods such as the middle of the 21st century are at least as uncertain as
projections of future climate; hence, it is probably most advisable to use such
information as scenarios of change, or conditioning assumptions (IPCC, 1998).
Moreover, culture exerts important influences on socioeconomic processes, problemsolving
methods, and the like. The formation of coalitions, social movements, and educational
programs directed toward changing institutional norms that might influence people’s
behavior concerning climatic change is culturally determined, like other complex
social and psychological processes. Cultural processes and economic behavior,
for example, can be modeled to capture some of the complexity of the social
processes, structures, and cognitive behavior involving culture (e.g., Rotmans
and van Asselt, 1996; Koizumi and Lundstedt, 1998). Thus, it is simply impossible
to predict with high confidence how societies and economies will develop in
the future—hence the extent to which they will have the capacity needed for
adaptation. The use of scenarios to assess driving forces and adaptive capacity
is one way to explicitly acknowledge these kinds of structural uncertainties
(e.g., IPCC, 2000). Socioeconomic scenarios, as already noted, are not predictions
of future states of the world but consistent and plausible sets of assumptions
about issues such as population growth, economic development, values, and institutions.
Although the emphasis on adaptation to reduce vulnerability and take advantage
of emerging opportunities is increasing in impact assessment, many uncertainties
remain regarding the effectiveness of different options, the relationship between
adaptation to short-term climate fluctuations and long-term climate change,
and constraints and opportunities that will be imposed by factors such as existing
institutional structures, economic and financial limitations, and cultural resistance
(IPCC, 1998).
1.5.3. Risk and Uncertainty
Uncertainties are pervasive throughout climate change impact assessment. For
some sectors, such as agriculture, uncertainty is large enough to prevent a
highly confident assessment of even the sign of the impacts. Until a few years
ago, uncertainties in assessments were so great that few researchers were willing
to carry their analysis through to numerical estimates of monetary impacts.
Even today, as the applicability of subjective probabilities is becoming more
accepted, impact estimates with explicit confidence intervals are the exception
rather than the rule (a few exceptions are Peck and Teisberg, 1992; Hope et
al., 1993; Nordhaus, 1994a; Manne and Richels, 1995; Morgan and Dowlatabadi,
1996; Titus and Narayanan, 1996; Roughgarden and Schneider, 1999). Figure
2-2 (Moss and Schneider, 2000) graphically depicts how uncertainties in
emissions scenarios feed into uncertainties in carbon cycle response, climate
sensitivity, regional climate responses, and ranges of impacts in an “explosion”
or “cascade” of widening uncertainty bounds. However, despite this daunting
expansion of uncertainty, methods to classify and formally treat such uncertainties
via subjective probability distributions are available in the literature (see
Box 1-2 and Section 2.6) and
can help to clarify which subcomponents of the overall human-environment system
are most critical to integrated assessments of the costs and benefits of climatic
changes or climate policies.
1.5.4. Low-Probability Catastrophic Events
Efforts to deal with low-probability, potentially catastrophic events in integrated
assessments of climate change are not well-represented in the literature. One
possibility would be to treat these risks like any hazard and use methods from
risk analysis: The value of the risk is the probability of occurrence multiplied
by the consequences of the event. For rare and catastrophic possibilities, there
is very little frequency data; thus, probabilities assessed are based largely
on subjective methods (e.g., Nordhaus, 1994b; Roughgarden and Schneider, 1999).
Equally important, under these conditions the expected cost estimate would be
very sensitive to the analyst’s (subjective) assumptions about the costs of
catastrophic events. Subjective probabilities can vary widely from analyst to
analyst under such conditions. This partly explains why most analysts have been
reluctant to include low-probability but potentially catastrophic events in
integrated assessments (for a recent exception, see Mastrandrea and Schneider,
2001). However, absence of analysis does not necessarily imply absence of risk,
and many risk management decisions in the private and public sectors are based
on strategic hedging against low-probability but highly costly possibilities,
such as insurance and deterrence (see Chapter 8). However,
the expected cost approach would imply a risk neutrality—an uncomfortable position
for those holding risk averse values in the face of possibilities such as collapse
of the “conveyor belt” circulation in the North Atlantic Ocean (e.g., Broecker,
1997; Rahmstorf, 1999; Chapter 19) or melting of the West
Antarctic Ice Sheet (e.g., Oppenheimer, 1998). Risk-averse individuals often
worry about the possibility that a forecast for a high-consequence event is
either accurate or an underestimate—the “type 2 error.” Such individuals have
argued that a better way to treat the possibility of catastrophe is to ensure
that all possible efforts are taken to avoid it—the “precautionary principle”
(see, e.g., Wiener, 1995). However, spending valuable, limited resources to
hedge against possible catastrophic outcomes with a low probability of occurring
is infeasible in practice; scarce resources could have been used more productively
elsewhere, including dealing with more probable climatic threats. People who
are concerned about “squandering” resources on what they perceive to be unlikely
threats or even an erroneous forecast—the “type 1 error”—often are engaged in
contentious debates with those more concerned with type 2 errors—a situation
that is well-known in risk management disciplines. Thus, it is difficult to
apply the precautionary principle unambiguously to justify a hedging strategy
against a potential catastrophic climatic event without also applying it to
the possibility of negative outcomes from the hedging strategy itself, then
weighing the relative risks of type 1 versus type 2 errors (Wiener, 1995).
1.5.5. Valuation Methods—Monetary Measures or Multiple Numeraires
Although much progress on valuation techniques is being made, as noted in Box
1-2, uncertainties are still large, and many impact estimates are “highly
speculative” (Nordhaus and Boyer, 2000). Impacts can be divided into market
and nonmarket impacts.
Market impacts occur in sectors or activities such as agriculture, forestry,
provision of water, insurance against extreme events, transportation, tourism,
and activities that use low-lying coastal land. Where these activities produce
marketed goods, a monetary estimate of impacts (in units of dollars per °C,
for example) sometimes can be made with fairly straightforward techniques, at
least under present-day conditions; this has been the most common approach in
impact studies to date (e.g., Mendelsohn et al., 2000). Market prices, adjusted
to correct for market distortions (e.g., externalities), are the appropriate
measure for unit impacts. Although the techniques are well established, the
numbers obtained still are approximate as a result of all the uncertainties
that surround impact assessments. Working out how the impacts will unfold in
the distant future is much less straightforward. Impacts could increase as the
intensity and scale of the activity increases (e.g., loss of coastal property)
or decrease as more modern and robust systems replace existing ones (e.g., new
crop strains are introduced with more climatic adaptability). Also, as noted
in Box 1-2, impacts expressed in economic terms
embed the values people attribute to the impacts across several numeraires,
as well as the values of future generations (see Section 2.5.6
for further elaborations).
For example, the use of highly aggregated decision analysis frameworks (see
Box 1-2 and Chapter 2)
can be controversial because aggregation of positive and negative costs of even
a limited number of market category sectors involves the arithmetic sum of many
subelements that contain large uncertainties and are related to different regions.
Furthermore, important market costs could be incurred by political instability
(e.g., Kennedy et al., 1998), migration of displaced persons (e.g., Myers, 1993),
diminished capacity of damaged ecosystems to provide accustomed services (e.g.,
Daily, 1997), or loss of heritage sites from sea-level rise (e.g., Schneider
et al., 2000b). Moreover, losses in nonmonetary categories (i.e., other numeraires
such as biodiversity lost, lives lost, quality of life degraded, or inequity
generated—all per °C) are very controversial (e.g., Goulder and Kennedy, 1997,
discuss attempts to estimate the intrinsic value of species). Any aggregation
over such numeraires into a common metric—usually the dollar—cannot be accomplished
transparently unless a variety of assumptions are explicitly given for the valuation
of each of these numeraires before aggregation hides the underlying assumptions
of how valuation was accomplished.
1.5.6. Damage Aggregation and Distributional Effects
Aggregation of various damages into a single estimate sometimes is appropriate
to provide policymakers with information about the magnitude of damages that
can be expected on a global scale. However, as noted in Box
1-2, Section 1.5.5, and Section 2.6.4,
there also is the risk that such aggregation conceals rather than highlights
some of the critical issues and value-laden assumptions that are at stake.
As a hypothetical but concrete example, assume that climatic change would cause
destruction of lives, ecosystems, and property in Bangladesh, corresponding
to a loss of 80% of its GDP. This loss to Bangladesh would amount to roughly
0.1% of global GDP. If the global economy grows at 2% yr-1, this
assumed impact on Bangladesh would correspond to a delay in global income growth
of less than 3 weeks. It is debatable whether adding, say, the possible benefits
for temperate agriculture to the losses of lives resulting from sea-level rise
in Bangladesh helps to assess the severity of climate change impacts because
the “winner” does not compensate the “loser” (i.e., benefits for temperate agriculture
offer little relief to those who have been affected by sea-level rise in other
regions). Authors in the literature have expressed concern about trading the
costs of emission reduction in some countries (e.g., more efficient end-use
energy technologies) with large-scale losses of lives and human health in others
(e.g., Munasinghe, 2000). Still, this is implicitly done in most conventional
cost-benefit analyses of climate change available in the literature. As noted
above and in Section 2.6.4, this points to the necessity
of using appropriately disaggregated cost and benefit data to make the analysis
more transparent. Possible ways of incorporating equity concerns include use
of distributional weights in cost-benefit analysis (e.g., Azar and Sterner,
1996; Fankhauser et al., 1997; Azar, 1999).
Owing to the complexities of valuation and aggregation analyses described above
and in the preceding subsection, the TAR authors are cautious about the applicability
of single “optimal” answers. Instead, they attempt to examine ranges of outcomes
calculated under a variety of assumptions available in the literature, for which
alternative valuation methods can be applied to different categories across
various numeraires.
|