6.2.3 Mixes of National Policy Instruments
Section 6.2.2 discusses various policy instruments to
manage GHG emissions in isolation. Various authors (e.g., Bernstein, 1993; Richards,
1998; Stavins, 1998b) argue that to select the best approach to attain the environmental
goal, various cost and other aspects must be taken into account. These include
production costs, cost differences across sources, transaction costs, monitoring
and enforcement costs, implementation, administrative costs, and other socio-economic
conditions idiosyncratic to each country. For these reasons, it can be anticipated
that in most countries GHG emissions will be managed using a portfolio of policy
instruments, rather than a single policy instrument. Furthermore, the portfolio
of instruments is likely to differ from country to country. Using a portfolio
of policy instruments enables a government to combine the strengths, while compensating
for the weaknesses, of individual policy instruments, thus improving overall
effectiveness and efficiency.
Under some conditions a combination of market-based and information policies
and regulations can improve economic efficiency. Well-designed policies aimed
at energy prices are economically most efficient when transaction costs are
low and/or cannot be substantially reduced through market transformation policies.
They also work best when the potential for technological learning by doing is
small or known with reasonable certainty. Well-designed regulatory and incentives-based
policies aimed at factors other than energy prices are economically most efficient
when the transaction costs are large and can be substantially reduced at low
administrative cost. They also work best when the potential for technological
learning by doing is large. Virtually all end-use markets for energy efficiency
suffer from high transaction costs and related market problems. Also, many energy
efficiency and renewables technologies exhibit large potentials for learning
by doing. The most effective and economically efficient approach to achieve
lower energy sector emissions is to apply market-based instruments, standards,
and information policies in combination. Policies to administer energy price
changes provide a uniform signal to all economic actors and overcome fragmentation.
Standards and information policies can move the economy closer to the frontier
of production possibilities, which raises total factor productivity.
Overriding non-economic reasons may also exist for combining different types
of policy instruments to manage GHG mitigation. First, the number and diversity
of sources is large and even the most comprehensive instruments (an emissions
tax or a tradable permit system) is not suitable for all of these sources. Second,
the conditions needed to administer efficiently these comprehensive instruments
(e.g., a manageable number of participants, but enough to create a competitive
market for a tradable permit system) may reduce the scope of their application.
Third, different policy instruments can be used to distribute the mitigation-cost
burden across sources in ways that lessen opposition to the policy goal. Fourth,
policy instruments have multiple impacts, so different instruments and sets
of impacts are preferred for different sources. Finally, governments have frequently
adopted a portfolio of policies, rather than a single policy instrument, to
deal with complex environmental issues.
One important aspect in the policy analysis has been a shift of attention from
the assessment of single policy instruments to questions of the optimal policy
mix (OECD, 1996b). Assessing the performance of particular environmental policy
instruments from historical evidence is difficult because these were often combined
in policy packages, as was the case with the phase-down of leaded petrol in
a number of European countries. Econometric analysis has been employed to separate
out the effects of individual policy instruments under such conditions, but
this is not always possible (Katsoulacos and Xepapadeas, 1996; Boom, 1998).
|